ORDER GRANTING, IN PART, AND DENYING, IN PART, [135] DEFENDANT'S MOTION TO DISMISS. Signed by Judge Trina L. Thompson on 6/17/2024. (rfm, COURT USER) (Filed on 6/17/2024)
Case No. 23-cv-01145-TLT
ORDER GRANTING, IN PART, AND
DENYING, IN PART, DEFENDANT’S
MOTION TO DISMISS
v.
TESLA, INC.,
Defendant.
RE: DKT. NO.
United States District Court
Northern District of California
Virginia M. Lambrix, Sean Bose, Patrick Doyle, Adriana Ferreira, Philomena Nana-
Anyangwe, Jason Pratti, Anthony Adjuder, Connor Shore, and Jason Pratti (collectively,
“Plaintiffs”), bring this antitrust putative class action lawsuit against Tesla, Inc. (“Defendant”),
individually and on behalf of “all persons or entities in the United States who paid for Tesla
Repair Services or Tesla-Compatible Parts from March 2019 to the present.” ECF No. 131, ¶ 218.
Plaintiffs assert causes of action for (1) Violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act (“Section 1”)
for Monopolization of the Tesla Repair Services Market, (2) Violation of Section 1 for
Monopolization of the Tesla-Compatible Parts Market, (3) Violation of Section 1 for Attempted
Monopolization of the Tesla Repair Services Market, (4) Violation of Section 1 for
Monopolization of the Tesla-Compatible Parts Market, (5) Violation of Section 2 of the Sherman
Act (“Section 2”) for Unlawful Tying, (6) Violation of the California Cartwright Act (“CCA”) for
Unlawful Tying, (7) Violation of the CCA for Combination in Restraint of Trade, and (8)
Violation of the Unfair Competition Law.
Before the Court is Defendant’s Motion to Dismiss Plaintiffs’ Second Consolidated
Amended Complaint. ECF No. 135.Page 2 Having carefully considered the parties’ briefs, oral arguments, relevant legal authority,
and for the reasons stated below, Defendant’s motion to dismiss is hereby GRANTED, IN PART,
DENIED, IN PART. Defendant’s motion is DENIED as to claims 1 through 5, and claim 7.
Defendant’s motion is DENIED as to claim 6, to the extent it relies on electric vehicles or parts as
the tying product. As conceded in Plaintiffs’ brief, Defendant’s motion is GRANTED with
prejudice as to claim 6, to the extent it relies on services as a tying product.
United States District Court
Northern District of California
I.
BACKGROUND
A.
Procedural History
This case arises from five related lawsuits. On March 14, 2023, Plaintiff Virginia Lambrix
filed a complaint against Tesla, Inc. See ECF No. 1. Upon filing of related case motions from
various parties, and a magistrate referral, this Court related four other actions filed against Tesla to
this case: Orendain v. Tesla, Inc., Case No. 23-cv-01157 (N.D. Cal) (filed Mar. 15, 2023; Bose v.
Tesla, Inc., Case No. 23-cv-01496, (N.D. Cal) (filed Mar. 29, 2023); Doyle v. Tesla, Inc., Case
No. 23-cv-01543 (N.D. Cal) (filed Mar. 31, 2023); Nana-Anyangwe v. Tesla, Inc., Case No. 23cv-02035 (N.D. Cal) (filed Apr. 26, 2023). See ECF Nos. 21, 35, 41.
On June 23, 2023, the Court consolidated the cases. See ECF No. 60. On July 17, 2024,
Plaintiffs filed their first amended consolidated complaint, bringing claims under the Sherman
Act, the CCA, and the UCL. ECF No. 63 (“First Consolidated Amended Complaint” or “FCAC”).
Two weeks later, Defendant filed a motion to dismiss and a motion to compel arbitration for
Plaintiffs Danielle Thys, Cary Phillips, and Levi Stoffal. See ECF Nos. 75–76. On September 27,
2023, the Court granted the motion to compel, and stayed the proceedings as to Thys, Phillips, and
Stoffal. See ECF No. 112. On November 17, 2023, the Court granted the motion to dismiss with
leave to amend, based on its finding that Plaintiffs had not “established that Tesla Repair Services
and Tesla-Compatible Parts are relevant single-brand aftermarkets, which caused all their federal
and state claims to fall short.” ECF No. 122 (“FCAC Order”), at 16. Page 3
On December 8, 2023, Plaintiffs filed the Second Consolidated Amended Complaint. ECF
No. 131 (“Second Consolidated Amended Complaint” or “SCAC”). On December 22, 2023,
Defendant filed a Motion to Dismiss and Request for Judicial Notice for exhibits attached to the
Motion. ECF No. 35 (“Motion”).
On April 2, 2024, the Court held a hearing on the filings, granted judicial notice or
incorporation by reference to Exhibits B, H, K, and L, and took the remaining filings under
United States District Court
Northern District of California
submission.
B.
Facts
Plaintiffs are individuals who reside in California, Colorado, Florida, and Maryland. See
SCAC ¶¶ 9–28. They are owners or lessors of battery-electric motor vehicles (“EVs”)
manufactured by Tesla. See id. Tesla is a multinational automotive and clean energy company
that designs, manufactures, and sells EVs that operate on public streets. See id. ¶ 29. Between
2019 and 2022, Defendant has fluctuated anywhere between 65% and 80% market share in the
United States EV market. See id. ¶ 53.
Because all EVs are designed differently, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla EVs can only be
maintained and repaired by a service provider “who specializes in the maintenance and repair of
Tesla EVs.” Id. ¶ 58–59. For car services, Tesla directs vehicle owners to Tesla-Owned Service
Centers, Tesla-Owned Collision Centers, or Tesla-Approved Collision Centers. Plaintiffs allege
that Tesla-Approved Collision (“TACCs”) centers are “independently owned, [but] are forced to
rely on Tesla itself to source Tesla-Compatible Parts and pricing.” Id. ¶ 66. Plaintiffs allege that
vague provisions in Tesla’s warranties stating that warranties will be void or coverage may be
excluded based on “improper maintenance, service or repairs,” effectively prevents owners from
repairing their own vehicles or using independent service-providers. Id. ¶ 182. Except for certain
“basic maintenance services (e.g., tire rotation), Plaintiffs claim that virtually all Tesla Repair Page 4
Services are performed” by the Tesla-Owned Centers or the Tesla-Approved Collision Centers. Id.
¶ 67.
Plaintiffs further allege that Tesla owners are “locked in” to using car parts that were
specifically designed to be compatible with Teslas. Id. ¶ 72. Tesla manufactures some components
for its EVs and purchases other components from suppliers around the world. Id. ¶ 156. Plaintiffs
claim that Tesla restricts the availability of Tesla-Compatible Parts “by, among other things,
United States District Court
Northern District of California
requiring at least some of its suppliers to enter into de facto exclusivity agreements.
preventing those suppliers from manufacturing Tesla-Compatible Parts for anyone other than
Tesla.” Id. ¶ 157. Further, Plaintiffs assert that Tesla has imposed various roadblocks preventing
independent service-providers from accessing Tesla-Compatible Parts and providing repair
services to Tesla owners. Although Tesla published a catalog of its parts in 2018, “numerous parts
in Tesla's catalog are unavailable for purchase” and “Tesla reportedly ignores parts requests from
independent.” Id. ¶¶ 91–92. Further, Tesla allegedly requires some purchasers to “provide a VIN
number and proof of vehicle ownership before it will sell certain parts,” which prevents
independent entities from providing repair services to consumers. Id. Finally, Tesla has exclusive
possession of a tool that is necessary to code and activate certain Tesla parts. Id. ¶ 93. Thus, many
parts that can be purchased from Tesla cannot be properly installed without assistance from Tesla.
Id. And many repairs require that the cars be put in “diagnostic” or “service” mode, and Plaintiffs
allege that Tesla “geo-fenced . . . their EVs so they would only enter diagnostic or service mode
when located in a Tesla Service Center or Tesla-Approved Collision Center.” Id. ¶ 148.
Plaintiffs allege that Tesla has limited the number of the independent Tesla-Approved
Collision Centers through imposition of onerous certification requirements and exposure to
various competitive risks. Id. ¶¶ 166–174. Plaintiffs also allege that, despite Tesla’s rapid growth,
Tesla has chosen not to invest in development of its Service and Collision Centers. Id. ¶ 175.
Plaintiffs assert that Tesla’s actions to restrict access to parts and services has forced Tesla owners Page 5
to pay supracompetitive prices for parts and services, while enduring extensive wait periods to
have their EVs fixed. Id. ¶ 192.
C.
Plaintiffs have supplemented their claims between the first and second consolidated
The Second Consolidated Amended Complaint
amended complaints. First, they clarified that none of the Plaintiffs were aware of any of the
repair restrictions described in the complaint. See SCAC ¶¶ 10, 12, 14, 16, 21, 23, 25, and 28.
United States District Court
Northern District of California
Second, they added specific allegations of price insensitivity, such that competition in the relevant
markets do not affect consumer demand of parts and services. See id. ¶¶ 60, 75. Third, they
clarified and added allegations to their pleading of significant information costs that prevent life-
cycle pricing and high switching costs. See id. ¶¶ 89–106. Last, they added various allegations
regarding Tesla’s purported anticompetitive conduct in both the EV foremarket and its
aftermarkets. See id.
II.
LEGAL STANDARD
Under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 12(b)(6), a defendant may move to dismiss an
action for failure to allege “enough facts to state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face.” Bell
Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 570 (2007). “A claim has facial plausibility when the
plaintiff pleads factual content that allows the court to draw the reasonable inference that the
defendant is liable for the misconduct alleged.” Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 678 (2009). “The
plausibility standard is not akin to a ‘probability requirement,’ but it asks for more than a sheer
possibility that a defendant has acted unlawfully.” Id. For purposes of ruling on a Rule 12(b)(6)
motion, the Court “accept[s] factual allegations in the complaint as true and construe[s] the
pleadings in the light most favorable to the nonmoving party.” Manzarek v. St. Paul Fire &
Still, the Court is not required to “assume the truth of legal conclusions merely because
they are cast in the form of factual allegations.” Fayer v. Vaughn, 649 F.3d 1061, 1064 (9th Cir. Page 6
2011) (quoting W. Mining Council v. Watt, 643 F.2d 618, 624 (9th Cir. 1981)). Mere “conclusory
allegations of law and unwarranted inferences are insufficient to defeat a motion to dismiss.”
Adams v. Johnson, 355 F.3d 1179, 1183 (9th Cir. 2004); accord Iqbal, 556 U.S. at 678.
Furthermore, “a plaintiff may plead herself out of court” if she “plead[s] facts which establish that
[s]he cannot prevail on h[er] . . . claim.” Weisbuch v. Cnty. of Los Angeles, 119 F.3d 778, 763 n.
(9th Cir. 1997) (quoting Warzon v. Drew, 60 F.3d 1234, 1239 (7th Cir. 1995)). “If there are two
United States District Court
Northern District of California
alternative explanations, one advanced by defendant and the other advanced by plaintiff, both of
which are plausible, plaintiff’s complaint survives a motion to dismiss under Rule 12(b)(6).”
Starr v. Baca, 652 F.3d 1202, 1216 (9th Cir. 2011).
III.
DISCUSSION
Plaintiffs allege eight causes of action: under Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act;
Sections 16720, 16726, and 16727 of the California Cartwright Act; and Section 17200 of
California’s UCL. See SCAC ¶ 1. Defendant argues that Plaintiffs do not state any viable claims
under federal and state law. See Motion, at 1.; see also Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6). The Court
addresses Plaintiffs’ claims below, first under the Sherman Act, then under the California
Cartwright Act, and finally under the UCL.
The Court applies Rule of Reason analysis to Plaintiffs’ claims.
A.
Courts categorize Sherman Act claims as either (1) per se claims, or (2) Rule of Reason
claims. Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 974. Per se claims arise out of restraints on trade that “always or
almost always tend[s] to restrict competition and decrease output.” Id. (citing Ohio v. American
Express Co., 585 U.S. 529, 541 (2018)). “When a per se prohibition applies, we deem a restraint
unlawful without any ‘elaborate study of the industry’ in which it occurs.” Epic Games, 67 F.4th
at 974 (citing Ohio, 585 U.S. at 541). Where a plaintiff does not allege a per se violation, their
claims are subject to the Rule of Reason analysis. This analysis generally requires a plaintiff to
define the relevant market and show that the “challenged restraint that harms consumers in the Page 7
relevant market.” Id. at 983 (quoting Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 585 U.S. 529, 543 (2018)).
“Given the costs of improperly condemning a practice across the board,” courts are
required to exercise “caution and judicial humility” before categorizing a practice targeted by the
plaintiff as a per se violation. Typically, only “‘horizontal’ restraints—restraints ‘imposed by
agreement with competitors’—qualify as unreasonable per se.” Ohio, 585 U.S. at 541. Vertical
price fixing is subject to Rule of Reason analysis. Id.. “Hybrid conspiracies,” in which a
United States District Court
Northern District of California
“manufacturer operates at two distinct levels . . . by acting as both a supplier and a distributor of
its own products,” and has an agreement with a competitor at one of these levels, are subject to the
Rule of Reason. Dimidowich v. Bell & Howell, 803 F.2d 1473, 1481-82 (9th Cir. 1986), modified
on unrelated grounds by Dimidowich v. Bell & Howell, 810 F.2d 1517, (9th Cir. 1987).
Here, Plaintiffs allege that its claims are based on per se violations of the Sherman Act.
Plaintiffs argue that their claims are based on horizontal restraints because Tesla has entered into
de facto exclusivity agreements with TACCs and Tesla-Compatible Parts manufacturers and
distributors, while also independently providing services and selling parts. Tesla, however, is also
a manufacturer of EVs, and utilizes TACCs to provide repair services to the EVs and the
manufacturers to manufacture and distribute certain parts. Thus, Plaintiffs’ claims are based on a
“hybrid conspiracy,” and are subject to the Rule of Reason.
B.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead the relevant markets.
In most Sherman Act cases where a plaintiff alleges that a defendant harmed market
competition, “[a] threshold step . . . is to accurately define the relevant market.” FTC v.
Qualcomm Inc., 969 F.3d 974, 992 (9th Cir. 2020). A plaintiff need not plead the existence of a
“Only when there is a possibility that the restraint in the market in which there is a horizontal
relationship will have significant procompetitive effects in the other market, as is the case when
the markets are for the service and the distribution of the same product, is rule of reason analysis
appropriate” for a hybrid arrangement. Dimidowich, 803 F.2d at 1481 n.6. To the extent Plaintiffs
could allege the parts or services market do not impose restraints on the EV markets, Plaintiffs’
claims may be categorized as per se violations.
1Page 8
market “with specificity,” and a proposed market definition will survive a Rule 12(b)(6) motion
unless it is apparent from the face of the complaint that the alleged market suffers a fatal legal
defect.” Newcal Industries, Inc. v. Ikon Office Solution, 513 F.3d 1038, 1045 (2008).
Here, Plaintiffs allege that Defendant’s anti-competitive conduct harmed competition in
the market for Tesla-Compatible Parts and Tesla Repair Services. Plaintiffs claim that Defendant’s
market power in the overall EV market enabled anti-competitive conduct in these aftermarkets.
United States District Court
Northern District of California
The Court evaluates the sufficiency of allegations supporting these markets below.
1.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead an EV submarket.
A market is defined as “the area of effective competition – i.e., the arena within which
significant substitution in consumption or production occurs.” Epic Games, Inc v. Apple, 67 F.4th
946, 975 (9th Cir. 2023) (citing Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 585 U.S. 529, 543 (2018)). “A market
comprises ‘any grouping of sales whose sellers, if unified by a monopolist or a hypothetical cartel’
could profitably raise prices above a competitive level.” Id. (citing Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v. Atl.
Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1434 (9th Cir. 1995)). Courts determine which products are included
in a certain market by evaluating what products have a “reasonable interchangeability of use or
sufficient cross-elasticity of demand with each other.” Id. (citing Hicks v. PGA Tour, Inc. 897 F.3d
1109, 1120 (9th Cir. 2018)). In making this determination, Courts evaluate empirical evidence,
such as a Small, Significant, Non-transitory Increase in Price (“SSNIP”) analysis, which uses
consumer data to establish whether a “hypothetical monopolist could profitably impose a Small,
Significant, Non-transitory Increase in Price above a competitive level.” Id.
Courts also consider whether a proposed market has the “practical indicia” of an
economically distinct market, including “[1] industry or public recognition of the [market] as a
separate economic entity, [2] the product’s peculiar characteristics and uses, [3] unique production
facilities, [4] distinct customers, [5] distinct prices, [6] sensitivity to price changes, and [7]
specialized vendors.” Id. (citing Brown Shoe v. U.S., 370 U.S. 294, 325 (1962)). A submarket Page 9
within a general product market can constitute a distinct market for purposes of an anti-trust claim.
Hicks, 897 F.3d at 1120; see Lucas Automotive Engineering, Inc. v. Bridgestone/Firestone, Inc.,
275 F.3d 762 (9th Cir. 2001) (“Lucas Auto.”) (holding that tires originally sold with vintage
automobiles could plausibly be a distinct submarket within the general market of all other tires
which could be used for vintage automobiles).
Plaintiffs define the EV market as “battery-electric motor vehicles designed and sold to be
United States District Court
Northern District of California
operated on public streets.” SCAC ¶ 39. The Court reiterates its holding that Plaintiffs have
plausibly alleged the existence of an EV market distinct from vehicles that use internal-
combustion engines (“ICE vehicles”). FCAC Order, at 9. As previously stated, EVs have peculiar
characteristics and uses, traveling shorter distances and requiring frequent charging. SCAC ¶ 44.
EVs and ICE vehicles require separate manufacturing processes and production facilities. See id.
¶ 52. For example, ICE vehicle plants are not accustomed to sourcing, producing, and
manufacturing battery packs for EVs. See id. Additionally, EVs are constructed with a different
kind of chassis, or frame, than ICE vehicles, and as a result, ICE production facilities cannot easily
be converted in EV production facilities. Id.
Plaintiffs further allege that EVs cost more than similarly equipped ICE vehicles. See id. ¶
40. For example, in April 2022, the average price of EVs was above $65,000, while all other
motor vehicles cost an average of $20,000 less. See id. Plaintiffs claim that “consumers do not
view EVs and ICE vehicles as interchangeable products”—indeed, a recent study reports that
“96% of EV owners will only buy another EV for their next vehicle.” Id. ¶ 45. For example,
Ford—a U.S. automaker—publicized its decision to reorganize its company and separate EVs and
ICE vehicles into separate businesses. See id. ¶ 51. As such, Plaintiffs plausibly alleged that the
public and industry analysts recognize EVs as a separate product market or submarket. See id. ¶
39. Page 10 Defendant argues that In re German Automotive Manufacturers Antitrust Litigation
(“German Auto.) weighs against finding the existence of an EV market. The Court disagrees, as
German Auto. presented distinct factual circumstances. In German Auto., the plaintiffs proposed a
market consisting entirely of diesel engine cars. Although the complaint implicitly acknowledged
that diesel engine cars competed with other cars that offered equivalent environmental and fuelefficiency benefits, the plaintiffs’ market definition excluded all such cars. Here, Plaintiffs
United States District Court
Northern District of California
proposed market consists of zero-emission battery-electric cars. Unlike in German Auto., there are
no options that offer similar or equivalent zero-emission vehicles.
Lucas Auto., however, is an insightful analog. There, the Ninth Circuit held that tire brands
that were used when a vintage car was first introduced could plausibly constitute a distinct market
from tire brands offered well-after the car was introduced, even though both brands could be used
on the vintage car today. 275 F.3d at 768. This holding was based, in part, on evidence suggesting
that vintage car consumers “absolutely insist[ed]” upon the original brand tires. Id. The Ninth
Circuit stated that “a legitimate inference can be drawn between the categorical insistence of
customers on, and to some degree their very strong preference for, [a product] and the expectation
that should the price of such [product] be increased, these customers would nonetheless purchase
the now-costlier version rather than substitute a less expensive, less authentic model.” Id.
Familiarly, here, Plaintiffs allege that 96% of EV owners would get an EV as their next car, which
creates a “legitimate inference” that these owners would purchase a costlier version. SCAC ¶ 51.
Thus, Plaintiffs sufficiently plead the existence of an EV market.
The fact that the Lucas Auto. Court had some evidence specific to price-inelasticity does not
diminish its relevance because: (1) that court was considering a motion for summary judgment
with a much higher standard, and (2) the evidence of price-inelasticity was relatively
underwhelming (e.g., a declarant “estimate[d]” that one-third of members of a vintage car club
would be willing to pay more for original tires.) 275 F.3d at 767–68. Page 11
2.
Plaintiffs sufficiently allege Tesla Repair Services, and the TeslaCompatible Parts, are cognizable, single-brand aftermarkets.
The relevant market can be a “single-brand aftermarket” where “demand for a good is
entirely dependent on the prior purchase of a durable good in a foremarket.” Epic Games, 67 F.4th
a single brand-aftermarket. An evaluation of the relevant law is below.
In Eastman Kodak Co v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, the plaintiffs alleged that
Kodak, which manufactured and sold photocopiers, engaged in anticompetitive conduct that
harmed the aftermarket for replacement parts and servicing of Kodak photocopiers. Kodak
United States District Court
Northern District of California
at 976 (emphasis omitted). The parties disagree on the proper test for determining the existence of
claimed that, because it did not have market power in the photocopier market, it could not
plausibly have market power in a single-brand aftermarket. Id. at 466. Kodak’s reasoning went as
follows: because the photocopier market was a competitive market in which it did not have market
power, consumers in that photocopier market would be able to identify Kodak’s attempts to charge
supracompetitive prices in the parts and services aftermarket and choose to buy a different
photocopier. Id. The existence of competition in the foremarket would discipline anti-competitive
conduct in the aftermarket, and it was thus irrational and implausible for Kodak to engage in anticompetitive conduct in an aftermarket when it did not have market power in the foremarket. Id.
The Supreme Court rejected this argument, finding that Kodak could engage in anti-competitive
conduct in single-brand aftermarkets without possessing market power in the foremarket. Even if
there was competition in the foremarket, the Court stated that consumers may not be aware of the
high prices in the aftermarket because of the difficulty most consumers would face in determining
maintenance prices for “complex, durable equipment.” Id. at 473–75. The Court further held that
the high cost of switching photocopiers would prevent existing consumers who learned about the
supracompetitive prices of services and repairs from switching. Thus, these consumers would be Page 12
“locked in” and forced to “tolerate some level of service price increases before changing
equipment brands.” Id. at 476.
Subsequently, the Ninth Circuit elaborated on the Kodak holding when presented with
similar claims where a defendant allegedly harmed a single-brand aftermarket without market
power in the foremarket. The Ninth Circuit found that contractual obligations were not a
“cognizable source of market power.” Thus, circumstances in which a “consumer’s selection of a
particular brand in the competitive market [was] the functional equivalent of a contractual
commitment,” could not form the basis for antitrust claims. Newcal Indus., Inc. v. Ikon Office
Solution, 513 F.3d at 1047 (citing Forsyth v. Humana, 114 F.3d 1467, 1476 (9th Cir. 1997))
United States District Court
Northern District of California
Recounting the history of Kodak and Newcal, the Ninth Circuit discussed the issues
presented by a lack of power in the foremarket in Epic Games¸ and aggregated the various
considerations, stating:
“to establish a single-brand aftermarket, a plaintiff must show: (1) the
challenged aftermarket restrictions are ‘not generally known’ when
consumers make their foremarket purchase; (2) ‘significant’
information costs prevent accurate life-cycle pricing; (3) ‘significant’
monetary or non-monetary switching costs exist; and (4) general
market-definition principles regarding cross-elasticity of demand do
not undermine the proposed single-brand market.”
67 F.4th at 977.
Here, Defendant alleges that Plaintiffs must meet all four Epic Games factors to establish
its single-brand aftermarket. Plaintiffs, however, argue that these factors only apply to cases in
which defendants do not have market power in the foremarket. Plaintiffs claim that, because they
allege that Defendant has market power in the EV market, and the Epic Games factors derive from
concerns about a lack of market power in the foremarket, these factors do not apply. This Court
agrees.
The Kodak Court established the information and switching costs factors to address
Kodak’s argument that it was impossible for a defendant to have market power in an aftermarket Page 13
without having market power in the foremarket. Eastman Kodak, at 504 U.S. at 467. In fact, the
Kodak Court explicitly declined to extend its analysis to a situation in which a defendant has a
market power in the foremarket. Id. at 465 n.10 (declining to address respondents’ argument that
Kodak had market power in the foremarket because it was not raised in their opposition to the
petition for certiorari, and stating that it would decide the case on the “premise . . . that
competition exists in the equipment market.”). The Ninth Circuit, in Newcal and Epic Games,
United States District Court
Northern District of California
acknowledged that these factors were established to determine whether competition in the
foremarket would be able to “discipline” a defendant’s conduct in the aftermarket. See Newcal,
513 F.3d at 1050; Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 946. In both cases, the Ninth Circuit recognized that
these inquiries were intended to evaluate whether consumers “ma[d]e a knowing choice to restrict
their aftermarket options when they decide in the initial (competitive) market to enter a [] . . .
contract.” Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 980–81 (emphasis added) (citing Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1050).
From a practical perspective, the relevance of information costs, switching costs, and
general knowledge of restrictions is reduced where a defendant has market power in the
foremarket. Market power is defined as the power to “force a purchaser to do something he would
not do in a competitive market.” Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 2080. Consumers in a foremarket
within which a company has market power have minimal ability to discipline the company’s
conduct in aftermarkets, regardless of information costs, switching costs, and general awareness of
restrictions.
For example, in Forsyth v. Humana, Inc., plaintiffs proposed a submarket that consisted of acute
care hospitals used by consumers insured by Humana, as supported by the fact that the vast
majority of Humana insureds used one acute care hospital as a result of Humana’s contractual
disincentives. 114 F.3d at 1476. The Ninth Circuit rejected this argument because the boundaries
of the market were defined by the consumers’ contractual obligations to Humana, which was an
improper basis to establish a market. Id. The Court held, however, that “to succeed in the face of
the contractual tie-in created by the insurance policies, the plaintiffs would have to make a
showing of monopoly power in the health insurance market, and there is no evidence of this.” Id. Page 14
The Court finds that Plaintiffs have (1) sufficiently alleged that Defendant has market
power in the EV foremarket, and (2) sufficiently alleged the existence of single-brand aftermarkets
for Tesla Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts. Arguendo, even if Plaintiffs have not
properly alleged market power in the EV market, Plaintiffs properly alleged the existence of these
aftermarkets under the Epic Games factors.
a.
United States District Court
Northern District of California
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead that Tesla possesses market power in
the EV Market.
Market power is defined as the power to “force a purchaser to do something he would not
do in a competitive market.” Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 2080. “The existence of such power
ordinarily is inferred from the seller’s possession of a predominant share of the market.” “Courts
generally require a 65% market share to establish a prima facie case of market power.” Image
Tech. Servs., Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195, 1206 (9th Cir. 1997) (citing American
Tobacco Co. v. United States, 328 U.S. 781, 797 (1946)); see Dreamstime.com, LLC v. Google
LLC, 54 F. 4th 1130, 1137 n.5 (9th Cir. 2022).
Here, Plaintiffs allege that Defendant had 65% to 80% market share in the EV foremarket
during the class period. SCAC ¶ 53. This factor is uncontested by Defendant. Consequently, the
Court finds that Defendant properly alleged market power in the EV foremarket.
b.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead the existence of aftermarkets for
Tesla Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts under
general market definition principles.
Plaintiffs must demonstrate that their proposed aftermarkets show the absence of
interchangeability and cross-elasticity of demand. In Eastman Kodak, the Supreme Court held that
the respondents’ services and parts aftermarkets met this criterion “[b]ecause service and parts for
Kodak equipment [were] not interchangeable with other manufacturers’ service and parts, the
relevant market from the Kodak equipment owner’s perspective [was] composed of only those
companies that service Kodak machines.” 504 U.S. at 482. Page 15 Here, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla’s electric vehicles “are designed differently and utilize
different parts that are not interchangeable with other EVs.” SCAC ¶ 58. A “Tesla EV owner must
bring his or her EV to a service provider who specializes in the maintenance and repair of Tesla
EVs.” Id. ¶ 59. Thus, service and parts for Teslas are not interchangeable with other EV
manufacturers. As a result, the aftermarkets are properly limited to Tesla-Compatible Parts and
Tesla Repair Services.
Defendant claims that Plaintiffs insufficiently plead that the proper geographic market for
United States District Court
Northern District of California
these aftermarkets is the United States. According to Defendant, a geographic market should be
limited to the area “where buyers can turn for alternative sources of supply,” and Plaintiffs do not
explain how “repair services in New Jersey could plausibly be a substitute for repair services in
California for a Tesla owner.” Motion, at 19 (citing Reilly v. Apple, Inc., 578 F. Supp. 3d 1098,
(N.D. Cal. 2022)). A market should “reflect commercial realities.” U.S. v. Grinnell Corp.,
U.S. 563, 572 (1966). Even where a consumer may primarily receive services from a local
provider, a geographic market that covers that the entire United States is appropriate where “the
business of providing such a service is operated on a national level.” Id. at 572. For purposes of a
motion to dismiss, Plaintiffs have plausibly alleged that the Defendant implemented its policies on
a nationwide level.
c.
Even if Plaintiffs were required to satisfy the Epic Games
factors, Plaintiffs sufficiently plead the existence of
aftermarkets.
Regardless of the existence of market power in the foremarket, Plaintiffs’ allegations
satisfy the Epic Games factors for purposes of surviving a motion to dismiss.
Defendant incorrectly claims that this Court already found in its prior order that Plaintiffs failed
to allege price sensitivity. Motion, at 10. The language from the Court’s order that Defendant cites
to for this contention addresses Plaintiffs’ allegations regarding price insensitivity in the EV
market, not in the Tesla-Compatible Parts or Tesla Services Market. FCAC Order, at 9 (“Plaintiffs
do not allege that EVs are insensitive.”) Page 16 (i)
Plaintiffs sufficiently allege they were generally unaware.
The first requirement, that the restrictions in the aftermarket are not generally known, is a
“crucial” one. Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 977 (quoting Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 477). This
unawareness requirement places “the burden on a plaintiff to ‘rebut the economic presumption
that . . . consumers make a knowing choice to restrict their aftermarket options’ when they make a
foremarket purchase.” Id. (quoting Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1050). “Kodak does not impose a
United States District Court
Northern District of California
requirement that a plaintiff show ‘complete ignorance’ of a defendant’s aftermarket restrictions; it
need only show that the restrictions are not ‘generally known.’” Id. at 979 n.10. While the Ninth
Circuit has not defined what, exactly, “amounts to general unawareness,” a plaintiff must present
at least some evidence to fulfill this prong. Id. at 979 n.10.
Plaintiffs provide an assortment of evidence that makes a plausible showing that
consumers were generally unaware of the aftermarket restrictions. In the SCAC, Plaintiffs cite an
article depicting Tesla owners that have experienced “unexpected headaches” with their cars,
which speaks to a general lack of consumer awareness of the alleged issues with Tesla EVs prior
to purchase. SCAC ¶ 87. Further, the SCAC indicates that Plaintiffs and consumers, generally,
were not aware of the repair restrictions and service center limitations described in the complaint.
See id. ¶¶ 10–28, 84–87.
Notably, Plaintiffs go further. They reason that consumers were unaware of the repair
restrictions in their warranties because Tesla misleads consumers into believing their EVs require
little to no maintenance, have fewer moving parts, and receive over-the-air software updates. See
id. ¶¶ 61, 94–95. See id. Despite Tesla publicizing freely available manuals, its electronic parts
catalog, and Toolbox diagnostic software, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla restricts individual shops and
car owners from conducting everything but the most minimal repair. See id. ¶ 88.
To this point, Defendant argues that Plaintiffs concede that consumers are knowledgeable
of Tesla’s restrictions as they are “now widely documented.” Motion, at 7 (emphasis added). The Page 17
critical and relevant inquiry is whether Tesla purchasers were generally unaware of aftermarket
restrictions at the time of foremarket purchase. If the Court were to follow Defendant’s logic, the
filing of this litigation could have made Tesla’s shortcomings and restrictions widely known,
thereby precluding Plaintiffs from pleading their case.
Several of the Plaintiffs purchased their Tesla EVs prior to the articles, tweets, and online
forums presented in the Second Consolidated Amended Complaint. Based on evidence cited by
United States District Court
Northern District of California
Plaintiffs, it is plausible that a significant portion of Tesla purchasers were unaware of their
vehicles’ forthcoming service and repair issues at the time of purchase. See, e.g., SCAC ¶ 87.
Plaintiffs must also sufficiently plead that they “did not knowingly enter a contract” that
would lock them into the aftermarkets associated with their foremarket Tesla EV. Epic Games,
F.4th at 977. Plaintiffs’ unawareness hinges on whether Plaintiffs were aware of the aftermarket
restrictions contained in their EV warranty. Tesla’s Parts, Body, & Paint Repair Limited Warranty
states that the warranty “may be voided, or coverage may be excluded, due to lack of or improper
maintenance, installation, service or repairs.” SCAC ¶¶ 182–86. Though Plaintiffs cite, and
Defendant highlights, an article describing consumers choosing “not to use independent repair
shops or aftermarket parts . . . for fear of losing warranty coverage,” it is plausible that consumers,
generally, were and remain unaware of these repair restrictions. SCAC ¶ 189. It is also plausible
that consumers learned of these issues after their Tesla EV purchase, either after coming across
such an article, or running into their own maintenance issue. In either case, consumer awareness,
conceivably, arose after purchase.
(ii)
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead significant information costs.
The second requirement is that “‘significant’ information costs prevent accurate life-cycle
pricing.” Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 977; see also Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 473–74. For
example, in Eastman Kodak, the Supreme Court held that photocopiers were “complex, durable
equipment” that presented significant information costs because they required a “sophisticated Page 18
analysis,” including “availability of products needed to operate, upgrade, or enhance the initial
equipment, as well as service and repair costs, including estimates of breakdown frequency, nature
of repairs, price of service and parts, length of ‘downtime,’ and losses incurred from downtime.”
Id. at 473–74.
Electric vehicles are as complex, if not more so, than the photocopiers addressed in
Eastman Kodak. Plaintiffs plausibly allege that “[i]t is difficult, if not impossible, for a consumer
United States District Court
Northern District of California
to accurately forecast how much repair and maintenance [] will be required” for their EVs. SCAC
¶ 103. Further, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla’s public misstatements distort the lifecycle costs for
Tesla. These alleged misrepresentations could plausibly hinder consumer ability to accurately
price the life of their vehicle at the time of purchase and make knowledgeable purchasing
decisions. See Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 473 (“For the service-market price to affect equipment
demand, consumers must inform themselves of the total cost of the “package”—equipment,
service, and parts—at the time of purchase; that is, consumers must engage in accurate lifecycle
pricing.”).
Plaintiffs also claim that lifecycle pricing is impossible because EVs are “a relatively new
product and Tesla is a relatively new producer.” SCAC ¶ 105. Because of the recency of this
industry, common variables of EV ownership may be extremely difficult to determine at the time
of purchase, “including the number of accidents one may have, how many miles the car will drive,
and how long the buyer will own the car,” making lifecycle pricing difficult. Id. at ¶ 104.
Plaintiffs further allege that three of the largest data providers used by automotive industry
professionals to estimate repair costs have no data on Tesla EVs. See SCAC ¶ 106. Thus, even if
a consumer wanted to and could synthesize the data presented to them to accurately price a Tesla,
they may not have the critical means to do so. Although the SCAC does provide an alternative
source for maintenance costs, see SCAC ¶¶ 204, 122, this does not defeat their argument. While
average yearly maintenance cost is one of the significant components to accurate lifecycle pricing Page 19
of a vehicle, it does not include the cost of collisions which can be significant. Further, it is not
clear when this information was posted online, and whether consumers would have had access as
early as 2019.
Regardless, Plaintiffs identify inconsistencies in Tesla’s sales and services that add
additional barriers to lifecycle pricing. Plaintiffs allege that Tesla sells its parts inconsistently both
to its own service centers and TACCs, which can frustrate a consumer’s vehicle price knowledge
United States District Court
Northern District of California
while keeping that consumer in the dark about how much the EV will cost long-term. See SCAC ¶
163. Plaintiffs further document a recurring practice by Tesla of refusing maintenance following
routine trivial fixes by third-party repair shops, or charging the full price to replace an out-of-
warranty part with minimal damage. Id. ¶¶ 188, 206–08. Plaintiffs have met their pleading burden
under this prong. It is beyond the scope of these proceedings to delve further into the distinctions
between the appropriate lifecycle pricing mechanisms and the mechanisms Plaintiffs use to
demonstrate market power, and ultimately becomes a question for the fact finders.
(iii)
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead high switching costs.
Third, a plaintiff must show that costs prohibit consumers from switching between market
goods such that a locked-in effect in the relevant market occurs. See Epic Games, 67 F.4th at
979–80; Eastman Kodak Co., 504 U.S. at 476–77 (“If the cost of switching is high, consumers
who already have purchased the equipment . . . will tolerate some level of service-price increases
before changing equipment brands.”). Switching costs must be “significant” to define a market.
Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S at 473; See Klein v. Facebook, Inc., 580 F. Supp. 3d 743, 781 (C.D. Cal.
2022) (holding that social media services have a high switching cost because users will be
reluctant to switch to a new platform “unless many other users make the switch simultaneously”).
A plaintiff need not make an extensive showing of switching costs; among other things, a plaintiff
can point to the “heavy initial outlay” of the foremarket good and brand-specific purchases.
Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S at 477. Page 20
In Eastman Kodak, the Court stated that evidence showing “the heavy initial outlay for
Kodak equipment, combined with the required support material that works only with Kodak
equipment, ma[de] switching costs very high for existing Kodak customers.” 504 U.S. at 477. In
other words, the high cost of Kodak’s complex foremarket equipment relative to and combined
with the restricted, necessary services and parts in the aftermarket made for high switching costs.
Plaintiffs tell a similar story here. Tesla EVs range from $40,000 to $110,000, and a
United States District Court
Northern District of California
purchase can be “one of the biggest purchases” in a consumer’s life. SCAC ¶ 99. Plaintiffs also
allege these purchases are often financed through loan or lease with specified contract terms that
exacerbate the total cost. See id. Plaintiffs further allege that Tesla EVs have some of the lowest
resale values in the EV market, making Tesla owners suffer a substantial loss if they were to make
a brand switch. See SCAC ¶ 100. This is in addition to the EV owners’ purchase of peripheral
products that only work with Tesla EVs, like home chargers that cost around $400. SCAC ¶ 101.
And even if they did make the switch to another EV brand, consumers could not escape Tesla’s
approach to alleged repair restrictions as other EV brands “not only have limited sales volume, but
. . . have also adopted similar policies, practices, and restrictions as . . . Tesla.” SCAC ¶ 82. The
high initial cost, investment required for peripheral products, and limited exit options sufficiently
support the existence of switching costs.
C.
Monopolization and Attempted Monopolization under Section 2 of the
Sherman Act
The Second Consolidated Amended Complaint alleges that Defendant monopolized, or
attempted to monopolize, the markets for Tesla Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts, in
violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act. SCAC ¶¶ 242–263; 15 U.S.C. § 2. The Court
addresses each of these allegations in turn. A Section 2 monopolization claim “has two elements:
(1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant market and (2) the willful acquisition or Page 21
maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a
superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.” Grinnell, 384 U.S. at 570–71.
a.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead that Tesla possesses monopoly power
in the relevant markets.
A plaintiff must establish that a defendant possesses monopoly power, which is the ability
“to control prices or exclude competition.” Grinnell, 384 U.S. at 571. Antitrust plaintiffs can
establish that a defendant possesses monopoly power via direct or indirect evidence. To establish
monopoly power via direct evidence, a plaintiff must provide “direct proof of injury to
competition,” including “evidence of restricted output and supracompetitive prices.” Forsyth,
F.3d at 1476. To prove monopoly power via “indirect evidence,” the plaintiff must “(1) define the
United States District Court
Northern District of California
relevant market, (2) show that the defendant owns a dominant share of that market, and (3) show
that there are significant barriers to entry and show that existing competitors lack the capacity to
increase their output.” Id.
Here, Plaintiffs provided direct and indirect evidence of monopoly power in the Telsa
Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts markets.
i.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead monopoly power in the Tesla
Repair Services market.
Plaintiffs provided sufficient direct and indirect evidence of monopoly power in the Tesla
Repair Services market to survive a motion to dismiss.
For direct evidence, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla has restricted output by reducing supply of
service-providers. Tesla has accomplished this, in part, by refusing to invest in its own service
center infrastructure, and limiting the growth of TACCs. Id. ¶ 151. Though Tesla EV sales have
increased substantially, service offerings have not. Id. ¶ 85. This has created delay and allowed
Tesla to charge supracompetitive prices.
Plaintiffs also provided sufficient indirect evidence of monopoly power. As discussed
above, Plaintiffs sufficiently defined the Tesla Repair Services market. Further, Plaintiffs plead Page 22
that Tesla has a dominant share of this market because virtually all Tesla services are performed
by Tesla or its “limited network of Tesla-Approved Collision Centers,” of which Tesla maintains
such tight control over that they are not competitors. Id. ¶ 67. This is because they must rely on
Tesla to source Tesla-Compatible Parts and to set pricing. See id. ¶ 66. To become a TACC, body
shops must purchase expensive equipment and undergo extensive training. Id. ¶¶ 170–72.
Plaintiffs also sufficiently allege the existence of barriers to entry into the Tesla Repair
United States District Court
Northern District of California
Services aftermarket. Tesla maintains its power over service due to the unique, computer-like
nature of its EV. Only Tesla can provide the full range of EV repairs and maintenance. SCAC ¶
90. It does this, Plaintiffs claim, by designing Tesla EVs to require remote diagnostic and
software updates that only it can provide. Id. Even if independent service providers have access
to the Toolbox software which offers some repair services, it is limited, expensive, and inadequate
to the point that consumers must still report to Tesla for such repairs. Id. ¶¶ 90, 144, 165. Indeed,
many of the parts used for maintenance and repairs will not function until they are coded by Tesla,
and no other provider can code these parts. Id. ¶¶ 92, 138-43, 147–50. Thus, Plaintiffs sufficiently
plead monopoly power in the Tesla Repair Services market.
ii.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead monopoly power in the TeslaCompatible Parts market.
Plaintiffs also provided direct and indirect evidence of monopoly power in the TeslaCompatible Parts markets to survive a motion to dismiss. For direct evidence, Plaintiffs allege that
Tesla has excluded manufacturer competitors and restricted output preventing Original Equipment
Manufacturers (“OEMs”) from selling “to anyone other than Tesla.” Id. ¶ 77. Plaintiffs also allege
that though Tesla may sell parts directly to consumers, it only does so on a limited basis. Id.
Plaintiffs also provide indirect evidence of monopoly power. Plaintiffs make the same
indirect argument as to Defendant’s near total control over the repair services market. Plaintiffs
further plausibly allege the significant barriers to entry and increased output for potential Page 23
competitors. For example, once consumers purchase a Tesla, similar to services, they are locked
into the Tesla-Compatible Parts aftermarket. Like Kodak, Plaintiffs allege there is no viable
substitute for Tesla parts and that most Tesla-Compatible parts are not interchangeable with other
EV parts. SCAC ¶ 72. Tesla’s batteries, for instance, cannot be serviced or replaced by anyone
but Tesla. Id. ¶ 179. Indeed, many of the parts used for maintenance and repairs will not function
until they are coded by Tesla, and no other provider can code these parts. SCAC ¶¶ 92–93.
United States District Court
Northern District of California
Plaintiffs further allege Tesla also prevents OEMs from manufacturing and selling TeslaCompatible Parts to anyone other than Tesla. SCAC ¶ 144. Thus, potential parts competitors face
numerous barriers to entry into the market, and Plaintiffs sufficiently plead monopoly power in the
Tesla-Compatible Parts market.
b.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead willful acquisition of power and
anticompetitive conduct.
Defendant recognizes, and Plaintiffs concede, that monopoly power on its own is not a
violation of the Sherman Act. “Mere possession of monopoly power, and the concomitant
charging of monopoly prices, is . . . an important element of the free market system.”
Dreamstime.com, LLC, 54 F.4th at 1137. The possession of monopoly power “will not be found
unlawful unless it is accompanied by an element of anticompetitive conduct.” Verizon Commc’ns
Inc. v. Law Offs. of Curtis V. Trinko, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004). To this end Plaintiffs plead that
Tesla’s conduct is anticompetitive. Plaintiffs plead that a series of Tesla decisions led to
insufficient availability of replacement parts and repair services to increase Tesla’s profits.
Plaintiffs claim Tesla was incentivized to keep as much market share of the aftermarkets as it
could with the expectation that these markets would become profitable in the long term. See
SCAC ¶ 151. This promise of profits explains, Plaintiffs allege, Tesla’s anticompetitive conduct
and why it has not invested further into the service and parts aftermarkets. See id. ¶ 150. Beyond
Tesla’s barriers to entry, limited diagnostic tools, misrepresentations, and warranty woes, Page 24
Plaintiffs allege Tesla has de facto exclusivity agreements preventing OEM and suppliers from
manufacturing Tesla-Compatible Parts for anyone other than Tesla. See id. ¶¶ 157–58. Tesla has
also authored cease and desist letters preventing independent repair shops from offering Tesla
repair services. See id. ¶ 162.
It is important not to confuse allegations of anticompetitive conduct with stifling the
innovation of a unique and cutting-edge consumer good. Anticompetitive conduct does not
United States District Court
Northern District of California
include “product improvement” nor innovations that attract consumers to a particular product due
to price, service, or terms advantages. Allied Orthopedic Appliances Inc. v. Tyco Health Care
Grp. LP, 592 F.3d 991, 999 (9th Cir. 2010). The existence of the alleged markets, market power,
and anticompetitive conduct are “factual question[s]” that “remain open for resolution” either for
or against Plaintiffs. Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1051. At this stage of the proceedings, Plaintiffs have
sufficiently alleged monopolization, or alternatively, attempted monopolization, in the Tesla
Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts markets in violation Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
D.
Tying Claims under Section 1 of the Sherman Act
Plaintiffs further allege that Defendant’s unlawful tying arrangement violates Section 1 of
the Sherman Act. SCAC ¶¶ 264–75. A tying arrangement is “an agreement by a party to sell one
product but only on the condition that the buyer also purchases a different (or tied) product, or at
least agrees that he will not purchase that product from any other supplier.” Kodak, 504 U.S. at
461. To establish the existence of a tie, a plaintiff must demonstrate that the arrangement includes
two or more distinct products, that the tie is “forc[ing] the buyer into a purchase of a tied product,”
and that the tie is unlawful. Id.
Here, Plaintiffs allege three separate tying arrangements: (1) the Tesla EV Market
foremarket is tied to both the Tesla-Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts aftermarkets (2)
the Tesla-Compatible Parts aftermarket is tied to the Tesla Repair Services aftermarket, and (3) the Page 25
Tesla Repair Services aftermarket is tied to the Tesla-Compatible Parts aftermarket. See SCAC ¶¶
269–71. As discussed below, Plaintiffs have sufficiently plead both prongs.
1.
Plaintiffs sufficiently allege the existence of distinct products.
To constitute two separate products, “[t]here must be sufficient consumer demand so that
it is efficient for a firm to provide” the products separately. See Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at (citing Jefferson Parish Hospital Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984)). “The efficiency showing
United States District Court
Northern District of California
may be inferred from ‘more readily observed facts.’ These include consumer requests to offer the
products separately, disentangling of the products by competitors, analogous practices in related
markets, and the defendant’s historical practice.” Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 995; see Eastman
Kodak, 504 U.S. at 463 (finding sufficient at the 12(b)(6) stage allegations that “consumers would
purchase service without parts” and that the defendant had sold them “separately in the past.”)
In Epic Games, the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals found the district court “clearly erred”
by not focusing on two products’ sufficient consumer demand when the district court found no tie.
67 F.4th at 996. Contrary to Apple’s assertion, Apple’s app distribution software and in-app
purchasing (IAP) platform could be separate markets because Apple separated them in other
contexts. Id. The court further found that because other companies sought to develop their own
IAPs, there was evidence of efficiency in and a separate market for the tied product. Id.
The Supreme Court in Eastman Kodak held that a tying arrangement existed between two
aftermarket products: Kodak parts and Kodak service. 504 U.S. at 463. The Court held that
petitioner provided sufficient evidence that “[a]t least some consumers would purchase service
without parts, because some service does not require parts, and some consumers, those who self-
service for example, would purchase parts without service.” Id. Kodak argued that there could
never be separate markets service for service and parts because there is no demand for parts
separate from service. Id. The Court, however, rejected this line of thinking because it would lead
to the illogical result that there could not separate markets for “cameras and film, computers and Page 26
software, or automobiles and tires.” Id. The Court also concluded that Kodak’s attempts to
bifurcate customers with different pay-rates—depending on whether they “serviced their own
machines or received third-party maintenance”—suggested product separation. Id. at 462.
Here, focusing on the first alleged tie, Tesla EVs in the foremarket can be separated from
the parts and services aftermarkets. Plaintiffs bring their claims because of Tesla’s chosen
practice to limit access to its service and parts to only Tesla and its approved providers, eroding
United States District Court
Northern District of California
Tesla’s service quality and secondary market value. See SCAC ¶¶ 3, 7. Plaintiffs also make the
contrast between automobile providers like Ford and their relatively abundant service and parts
provisions and that of Tesla’s. See id. ¶ 85. That collision centers and body shops outside of
Tesla are seeking to receive training, equipment, and parts suggests that, like the in-app
purchasing platform in Epic Games, there is efficiency and separation between Tesla EVs and its
aftermarkets.
Between services and parts, Plaintiffs sufficiently allege there is sufficient demand and
efficiency because service and parts have been sold separately in the past and are still sold
separately. In Eastman Kodak, the Court found that Kodak’s “policy of allowing customers to
purchase parts on condition that they agree to service their own machines suggests that the
demand for parts can be separated from the demand for service.” 504 U.S. at 462 n.5. Similarly,
Tesla’s warranty discourages Tesla EV owners from receiving service outside of Tesla by
suggesting that the warranty “may be voided or coverage may be excluded due to improper
maintenance, service or repairs.” SCAC ¶¶ 182–83. Further, Tesla’s over-the-air software updates
and diagnostic reports do not require any parts. See SCAC ¶¶ 94–95. This separation of
consumers who received Tesla service and those who went outside of Tesla to receive service
suggests the existence of a separate market for its parts and a separate market for service and
repair. Page 27 2.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead that the tying scheme coerced consumers.
“Even where a transaction involves separate products, it is not necessarily a tie; the seller
must also ‘force the buyer into the purchase of a tied product that the buyer either did not want at
all, or might have preferred to purchase elsewhere on different terms.’” Epic Games, 67 F.4th at
996 (citing Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 12).
Plaintiffs allege that consumers attempt to receive both services and parts outside of Tesla,
United States District Court
Northern District of California
but are coerced into forgoing those options to stay within warranty. See SCAC ¶ 189.
Specifically, Tesla forces consumers to purchase the tied product by threatening to void warranties
if consumers use non-Tesla certified service providers or if they use non-OEM parts. See id.; See
Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 12 (The seller must also “force the buyer into the purchase of a tied
product that the buyer either did not want at all or might have preferred to purchase elsewhere on
different terms.”). In Eastman Kodak, the plaintiffs were forced to receive services from only
Kodak due to unique machine parts, similarly, Tesla EV owners are limited in their options to
receive service and parts due to Tesla’s market power in the EV submarket and Tesla’s own
conduct. See Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 482. The EV parts and repair aftermarkets for Tesla
EVs and other EVs/ICE vehicles are not substitutes for each other, meaning there is no cross
elasticity of demand; this further aides Plaintiffs in their argument. See SCAC ¶¶ 57-59.
Finally, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla excludes competition in the repairs and parts market by
limiting diagnostic tools and manuals (Id. ¶¶ 226(f), 246(c)) and misleading consumers (Id. ¶¶ 61,
94-95). Plaintiffs claim that there is an insignificant number of independent service providers
because of Tesla’s Repair Restrictions. Even the TACCs which are “independent”, are not really
because they must rely on Tesla to source Tesla-Compatible Parts and pricing. Id. ¶ 66. Thus,
Plaintiffs have sufficiently plead that Tesla’s tying scheme coerces customers into undesired
purchases. Page 28 3.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead that the ties are unlawful.
“A tie can be unlawful pursuant to either a modified per se rule or the Rule of Reason. A
tie is per se unlawful if (1) the defendant has market power in the tying product market, and (2) the
“tying arrangement affects a ‘not insubstantial volume of commerce’ in the tied product market.”
Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 996–97 (quoting Blough v. Holland Realty, Inc., 574 F.3d 1084, (9th Cir. 2009)). As discussed above, Plaintiffs have sufficiently plead that Tesla possesses market
United States District Court
Northern District of California
power in all three markets. Further, given that Plaintiffs alleged that Tesla controls “virtually all”
of the commerce in the Tesla-Compatible Parts and Tesla Repair Services markets, it is plausible
to infer that these tying arrangements would affect a “not insubstantial volume of commerce” in
these markets. Thus, Plaintiffs have sufficiently plead tying claims.
E.
“The analysis under California's antitrust law mirrors the analysis under federal law
Plaintiffs sufficiently allege unlawful tying in violation of the Cartwright Act.
because the Cartwright Act, Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 16700 et seq., was modeled after the
Sherman Act.” County of Tuolumne v. Sonora Comm. Hosp., 236 F.3d 1148, 1160 (2001).
However, the Cartwright Act is distinct in that it does not apply claims in which “the tying item is
a service.” Morrison v. Viacom, Inc., 66 Cal. App. 4th 534, 546 (1998). In their opposition,
Plaintiffs appeared to concede that they were prohibited from asserting a tying claim under the
Cartwright Act based on Tesla Repair Services as the tying product. Oppo., at 21 fn.13 (“Tesla
asserts that Plaintiffs’ Cartwright Act claim alleging Tesla Repair Services as a tying product must
be dismissed. . . . Regarding that aspect and only that aspect of Plaintiffs’ claim, Tesla is correct.”)
As such, Plaintiffs’ Cartwright Act claim is dismissed to the extent it is based on a Tesla Repair
Services as the tying product. Plaintiffs’ Cartwright Act claims alleging that EVs and Tesla-
Compatible Parts as the tying products are maintained. Page 29
F.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead a combination in restraint of trade in violation of
the Cartwright Act.
Plaintiffs claim that Defendant’s de facto exclusivity agreements with the TACCs and
manufacturers constitute horizontal restraints that are per se violations of the Cartwright Act. The
Ninth Circuit has held that California courts would agree with its holding that hybrid agreements
are not per se violations. Dimidowich, 803 F.2d, at 1481–82. Thus, Plaintiffs’ claims are subject to
the Rule of Reason. Plaintiffs, again, argue that these restraints are per se violations of the law.
However, as stated above, plaintiff has not sufficiently plead that this hybrid conspiracy is a per se
violation. Thus, the Rule of Reason applies to these claims. The Rule of Reason applies
“essentially the same” regardless of “whether the alleged antitrust violation” is based on concerted
United States District Court
Northern District of California
or independent. As previously noted, Plaintiffs’ allegations regarding de facto exclusivity
agreements were sufficient to form the basis for independent unlawful restraints of trade. As such,
these allegations are sufficient to form the basis for concerted restraints on trade.
G.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead a violation of the California Unfair Competition
Law (UCL).
Plaintiffs allege that defendant violated the UCL which prohibits any unlawful, unfair, or
fraudulent business practice. See id. ¶¶ 303, 310. The statute’s “purpose is to protect both
consumers and competitors by promoting fair competition in commercial markets for goods and
services.” Abbott Labs. v. Superior Court, 9 Cal. 5th 642, 651 (2020) (citing Kasky v. Nike,
Inc. 27 Cal.4th 939, 949 (2002)). “By proscribing any unlawful business practice, section
borrows violations of other laws and treats them as unlawful practices that the unfair competition
law makes independently actionable.” Abbott Labs., 9 Cal. 5th at 651. (Internal citation omitted).
Here, Plaintiffs assert that Tesla engaged in both unlawful and unfair business practices. SCAC ¶¶
303, 310. Since Plaintiffs have sufficiently pled the elements for relief under the Sherman Act and
Cartwright Act, Plaintiffs sufficiently plead unlawful business practices in violation of the UCL. Page 30
V.
CONCLUSION
The Court finds that Plaintiffs have plausibly alleged a cause of action for monopolization
and unlawful tying under the Sherman act and causes of action under the Cartwright and
California UCL.
Accordingly, for the foregoing reasons the Court DENIES Defendant’s Motion as to
United States District Court
Northern District of California
claims 1 through 5 and 7. The Court further DENIES claim 6 to the extent it relies on EVs or
Tesla-Compatible Parts as a tying product. The Court GRANTS Defendant’s Motion, with
prejudice, as to claim 6 to the extent it relies on services as a tying product.
This resolves docket number 135.
IT IS SO ORDERED.
Dated: June 17,
TRINA L. THOMPSON
United States District Judge
PDF Page 1
PlainSite Cover Page
PDF Page 2
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 1 of 30
1
2
3
UNITED STATES DISTRICT COURT
4
NORTHERN DISTRICT OF CALIFORNIA
5
6
VIRGINIA M LAMBRIX, et al.,
Plaintiffs,
7
8
9
10
Case No. 23-cv-01145-TLT
ORDER GRANTING, IN PART, AND
DENYING, IN PART, DEFENDANT’S
MOTION TO DISMISS
v.
TESLA, INC.,
Defendant.
RE: DKT. NO. 135
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
12
Virginia M. Lambrix, Sean Bose, Patrick Doyle, Adriana Ferreira, Philomena Nana-
13
Anyangwe, Jason Pratti, Anthony Adjuder, Connor Shore, and Jason Pratti (collectively,
14
“Plaintiffs”), bring this antitrust putative class action lawsuit against Tesla, Inc. (“Defendant”),
15
individually and on behalf of “all persons or entities in the United States who paid for Tesla
16
Repair Services or Tesla-Compatible Parts from March 2019 to the present.” ECF No. 131, ¶ 218.
17
Plaintiffs assert causes of action for (1) Violation of Section 1 of the Sherman Act (“Section 1”)
18
19
20
for Monopolization of the Tesla Repair Services Market, (2) Violation of Section 1 for
Monopolization of the Tesla-Compatible Parts Market, (3) Violation of Section 1 for Attempted
21
Monopolization of the Tesla Repair Services Market, (4) Violation of Section 1 for
22
Monopolization of the Tesla-Compatible Parts Market, (5) Violation of Section 2 of the Sherman
23
Act (“Section 2”) for Unlawful Tying, (6) Violation of the California Cartwright Act (“CCA”) for
24
Unlawful Tying, (7) Violation of the CCA for Combination in Restraint of Trade, and (8)
25
Violation of the Unfair Competition Law.
26
27
28
Before the Court is Defendant’s Motion to Dismiss Plaintiffs’ Second Consolidated
Amended Complaint. ECF No. 135.
PDF Page 3
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 2 of 30
Having carefully considered the parties’ briefs, oral arguments, relevant legal authority,
1
2
and for the reasons stated below, Defendant’s motion to dismiss is hereby GRANTED, IN PART,
3
DENIED, IN PART. Defendant’s motion is DENIED as to claims 1 through 5, and claim 7.
4
Defendant’s motion is DENIED as to claim 6, to the extent it relies on electric vehicles or parts as
5
the tying product. As conceded in Plaintiffs’ brief, Defendant’s motion is GRANTED with
6
prejudice as to claim 6, to the extent it relies on services as a tying product.
7
8
9
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
I.
BACKGROUND
A.
Procedural History
This case arises from five related lawsuits. On March 14, 2023, Plaintiff Virginia Lambrix
11
filed a complaint against Tesla, Inc. See ECF No. 1. Upon filing of related case motions from
12
various parties, and a magistrate referral, this Court related four other actions filed against Tesla to
13
this case: Orendain v. Tesla, Inc., Case No. 23-cv-01157 (N.D. Cal) (filed Mar. 15, 2023; Bose v.
14
Tesla, Inc., Case No. 23-cv-01496, (N.D. Cal) (filed Mar. 29, 2023); Doyle v. Tesla, Inc., Case
15
16
17
18
No. 23-cv-01543 (N.D. Cal) (filed Mar. 31, 2023); Nana-Anyangwe v. Tesla, Inc., Case No. 23cv-02035 (N.D. Cal) (filed Apr. 26, 2023). See ECF Nos. 21, 35, 41.
On June 23, 2023, the Court consolidated the cases. See ECF No. 60. On July 17, 2024,
19
Plaintiffs filed their first amended consolidated complaint, bringing claims under the Sherman
20
Act, the CCA, and the UCL. ECF No. 63 (“First Consolidated Amended Complaint” or “FCAC”).
21
Two weeks later, Defendant filed a motion to dismiss and a motion to compel arbitration for
22
Plaintiffs Danielle Thys, Cary Phillips, and Levi Stoffal. See ECF Nos. 75–76. On September 27,
23
24
2023, the Court granted the motion to compel, and stayed the proceedings as to Thys, Phillips, and
25
Stoffal. See ECF No. 112. On November 17, 2023, the Court granted the motion to dismiss with
26
leave to amend, based on its finding that Plaintiffs had not “established that Tesla Repair Services
27
and Tesla-Compatible Parts are relevant single-brand aftermarkets, which caused all their federal
28
and state claims to fall short.” ECF No. 122 (“FCAC Order”), at 16.
2
PDF Page 4
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 3 of 30
1
On December 8, 2023, Plaintiffs filed the Second Consolidated Amended Complaint. ECF
2
No. 131 (“Second Consolidated Amended Complaint” or “SCAC”). On December 22, 2023,
3
Defendant filed a Motion to Dismiss and Request for Judicial Notice for exhibits attached to the
4
Motion. ECF No. 35 (“Motion”).
5
6
On April 2, 2024, the Court held a hearing on the filings, granted judicial notice or
incorporation by reference to Exhibits B, H, K, and L, and took the remaining filings under
7
8
9
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
submission.
B.
Facts
Plaintiffs are individuals who reside in California, Colorado, Florida, and Maryland. See
11
SCAC ¶¶ 9–28. They are owners or lessors of battery-electric motor vehicles (“EVs”)
12
manufactured by Tesla. See id. Tesla is a multinational automotive and clean energy company
13
that designs, manufactures, and sells EVs that operate on public streets. See id. ¶ 29. Between
14
2019 and 2022, Defendant has fluctuated anywhere between 65% and 80% market share in the
15
16
17
United States EV market. See id. ¶ 53.
Because all EVs are designed differently, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla EVs can only be
18
maintained and repaired by a service provider “who specializes in the maintenance and repair of
19
Tesla EVs.” Id. ¶ 58–59. For car services, Tesla directs vehicle owners to Tesla-Owned Service
20
Centers, Tesla-Owned Collision Centers, or Tesla-Approved Collision Centers. Plaintiffs allege
21
22
that Tesla-Approved Collision (“TACCs”) centers are “independently owned, [but] are forced to
rely on Tesla itself to source Tesla-Compatible Parts and pricing.” Id. ¶ 66. Plaintiffs allege that
23
24
vague provisions in Tesla’s warranties stating that warranties will be void or coverage may be
25
excluded based on “improper maintenance, service or repairs,” effectively prevents owners from
26
repairing their own vehicles or using independent service-providers. Id. ¶ 182. Except for certain
27
“basic maintenance services (e.g., tire rotation), Plaintiffs claim that virtually all Tesla Repair
28
3
PDF Page 5
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 4 of 30
1
2
Services are performed” by the Tesla-Owned Centers or the Tesla-Approved Collision Centers. Id.
¶ 67.
3
Plaintiffs further allege that Tesla owners are “locked in” to using car parts that were
4
specifically designed to be compatible with Teslas. Id. ¶ 72. Tesla manufactures some components
5
6
for its EVs and purchases other components from suppliers around the world. Id. ¶ 156. Plaintiffs
claim that Tesla restricts the availability of Tesla-Compatible Parts “by, among other things,
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
requiring at least some of its suppliers to enter into de facto exclusivity agreements.
preventing those suppliers from manufacturing Tesla-Compatible Parts for anyone other than
10
Tesla.” Id. ¶ 157. Further, Plaintiffs assert that Tesla has imposed various roadblocks preventing
11
independent service-providers from accessing Tesla-Compatible Parts and providing repair
12
services to Tesla owners. Although Tesla published a catalog of its parts in 2018, “numerous parts
13
in Tesla's catalog are unavailable for purchase” and “Tesla reportedly ignores parts requests from
14
independent.” Id. ¶¶ 91–92. Further, Tesla allegedly requires some purchasers to “provide a VIN
15
16
number and proof of vehicle ownership before it will sell certain parts,” which prevents
17
independent entities from providing repair services to consumers. Id. Finally, Tesla has exclusive
18
possession of a tool that is necessary to code and activate certain Tesla parts. Id. ¶ 93. Thus, many
19
parts that can be purchased from Tesla cannot be properly installed without assistance from Tesla.
20
Id. And many repairs require that the cars be put in “diagnostic” or “service” mode, and Plaintiffs
21
22
allege that Tesla “geo-fenced . . . their EVs so they would only enter diagnostic or service mode
when located in a Tesla Service Center or Tesla-Approved Collision Center.” Id. ¶ 148.
23
24
Plaintiffs allege that Tesla has limited the number of the independent Tesla-Approved
25
Collision Centers through imposition of onerous certification requirements and exposure to
26
various competitive risks. Id. ¶¶ 166–174. Plaintiffs also allege that, despite Tesla’s rapid growth,
27
Tesla has chosen not to invest in development of its Service and Collision Centers. Id. ¶ 175.
28
Plaintiffs assert that Tesla’s actions to restrict access to parts and services has forced Tesla owners
4
PDF Page 6
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 5 of 30
1
2
to pay supracompetitive prices for parts and services, while enduring extensive wait periods to
have their EVs fixed. Id. ¶ 192.
3
C.
4
Plaintiffs have supplemented their claims between the first and second consolidated
5
6
The Second Consolidated Amended Complaint
amended complaints. First, they clarified that none of the Plaintiffs were aware of any of the
repair restrictions described in the complaint. See SCAC ¶¶ 10, 12, 14, 16, 21, 23, 25, and 28.
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
Second, they added specific allegations of price insensitivity, such that competition in the relevant
markets do not affect consumer demand of parts and services. See id. ¶¶ 60, 75. Third, they
10
clarified and added allegations to their pleading of significant information costs that prevent life-
11
cycle pricing and high switching costs. See id. ¶¶ 89–106. Last, they added various allegations
12
regarding Tesla’s purported anticompetitive conduct in both the EV foremarket and its
13
aftermarkets. See id.
14
II.
LEGAL STANDARD
15
16
Under Federal Rule of Civil Procedure 12(b)(6), a defendant may move to dismiss an
17
action for failure to allege “enough facts to state a claim to relief that is plausible on its face.” Bell
18
Atl. Corp. v. Twombly, 550 U.S. 544, 570 (2007). “A claim has facial plausibility when the
19
plaintiff pleads factual content that allows the court to draw the reasonable inference that the
20
defendant is liable for the misconduct alleged.” Ashcroft v. Iqbal, 556 U.S. 662, 678 (2009). “The
21
22
plausibility standard is not akin to a ‘probability requirement,’ but it asks for more than a sheer
possibility that a defendant has acted unlawfully.” Id. For purposes of ruling on a Rule 12(b)(6)
23
24
motion, the Court “accept[s] factual allegations in the complaint as true and construe[s] the
25
pleadings in the light most favorable to the nonmoving party.” Manzarek v. St. Paul Fire &
26
Marine Ins. Co., 519 F.3d 1025, 1031 (9th Cir. 2008).
27
28
Still, the Court is not required to “assume the truth of legal conclusions merely because
they are cast in the form of factual allegations.” Fayer v. Vaughn, 649 F.3d 1061, 1064 (9th Cir.
5
PDF Page 7
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 6 of 30
1
2011) (quoting W. Mining Council v. Watt, 643 F.2d 618, 624 (9th Cir. 1981)). Mere “conclusory
2
allegations of law and unwarranted inferences are insufficient to defeat a motion to dismiss.”
3
Adams v. Johnson, 355 F.3d 1179, 1183 (9th Cir. 2004); accord Iqbal, 556 U.S. at 678.
4
Furthermore, “a plaintiff may plead herself out of court” if she “plead[s] facts which establish that
5
[s]he cannot prevail on h[er] . . . claim.” Weisbuch v. Cnty. of Los Angeles, 119 F.3d 778, 763 n.1
6
(9th Cir. 1997) (quoting Warzon v. Drew, 60 F.3d 1234, 1239 (7th Cir. 1995)). “If there are two
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
alternative explanations, one advanced by defendant and the other advanced by plaintiff, both of
which are plausible, plaintiff’s complaint survives a motion to dismiss under Rule 12(b)(6).”
10
Starr v. Baca, 652 F.3d 1202, 1216 (9th Cir. 2011).
11
III.
12
13
14
DISCUSSION
Plaintiffs allege eight causes of action: under Sections 1 and 2 of the Sherman Act;
Sections 16720, 16726, and 16727 of the California Cartwright Act; and Section 17200 of
California’s UCL. See SCAC ¶ 1. Defendant argues that Plaintiffs do not state any viable claims
15
16
under federal and state law. See Motion, at 1.; see also Fed. R. Civ. P. 12(b)(6). The Court
17
addresses Plaintiffs’ claims below, first under the Sherman Act, then under the California
18
Cartwright Act, and finally under the UCL.
The Court applies Rule of Reason analysis to Plaintiffs’ claims.
19
A.
20
Courts categorize Sherman Act claims as either (1) per se claims, or (2) Rule of Reason
21
22
claims. Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 974. Per se claims arise out of restraints on trade that “always or
almost always tend[s] to restrict competition and decrease output.” Id. (citing Ohio v. American
23
24
Express Co., 585 U.S. 529, 541 (2018)). “When a per se prohibition applies, we deem a restraint
25
unlawful without any ‘elaborate study of the industry’ in which it occurs.” Epic Games, 67 F.4th
26
at 974 (citing Ohio, 585 U.S. at 541). Where a plaintiff does not allege a per se violation, their
27
claims are subject to the Rule of Reason analysis. This analysis generally requires a plaintiff to
28
define the relevant market and show that the “challenged restraint that harms consumers in the
6
PDF Page 8
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 7 of 30
1
relevant market.” Id. at 983 (quoting Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 585 U.S. 529, 543 (2018)).
2
“Given the costs of improperly condemning a practice across the board,” courts are
3
required to exercise “caution and judicial humility” before categorizing a practice targeted by the
4
plaintiff as a per se violation. Typically, only “‘horizontal’ restraints—restraints ‘imposed by
5
agreement with competitors’—qualify as unreasonable per se.” Ohio, 585 U.S. at 541. Vertical
6
price fixing is subject to Rule of Reason analysis. Id.. “Hybrid conspiracies,” in which a
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
“manufacturer operates at two distinct levels . . . by acting as both a supplier and a distributor of
its own products,” and has an agreement with a competitor at one of these levels, are subject to the
10
Rule of Reason. Dimidowich v. Bell & Howell, 803 F.2d 1473, 1481-82 (9th Cir. 1986), modified
11
on unrelated grounds by Dimidowich v. Bell & Howell, 810 F.2d 1517, (9th Cir. 1987).
12
13
Here, Plaintiffs allege that its claims are based on per se violations of the Sherman Act.
Plaintiffs argue that their claims are based on horizontal restraints because Tesla has entered into
14
de facto exclusivity agreements with TACCs and Tesla-Compatible Parts manufacturers and
15
16
distributors, while also independently providing services and selling parts. Tesla, however, is also
17
a manufacturer of EVs, and utilizes TACCs to provide repair services to the EVs and the
18
manufacturers to manufacture and distribute certain parts. Thus, Plaintiffs’ claims are based on a
19
“hybrid conspiracy,” and are subject to the Rule of Reason.1
20
B.
21
22
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead the relevant markets.
In most Sherman Act cases where a plaintiff alleges that a defendant harmed market
competition, “[a] threshold step . . . is to accurately define the relevant market.” FTC v.
23
24
Qualcomm Inc., 969 F.3d 974, 992 (9th Cir. 2020). A plaintiff need not plead the existence of a
25
26
27
28
“Only when there is a possibility that the restraint in the market in which there is a horizontal
relationship will have significant procompetitive effects in the other market, as is the case when
the markets are for the service and the distribution of the same product, is rule of reason analysis
appropriate” for a hybrid arrangement. Dimidowich, 803 F.2d at 1481 n.6. To the extent Plaintiffs
could allege the parts or services market do not impose restraints on the EV markets, Plaintiffs’
claims may be categorized as per se violations.
7
1
PDF Page 9
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 8 of 30
1
market “with specificity,” and a proposed market definition will survive a Rule 12(b)(6) motion
2
unless it is apparent from the face of the complaint that the alleged market suffers a fatal legal
3
defect.” Newcal Industries, Inc. v. Ikon Office Solution, 513 F.3d 1038, 1045 (2008).
4
5
6
Here, Plaintiffs allege that Defendant’s anti-competitive conduct harmed competition in
the market for Tesla-Compatible Parts and Tesla Repair Services. Plaintiffs claim that Defendant’s
market power in the overall EV market enabled anti-competitive conduct in these aftermarkets.
7
8
9
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
The Court evaluates the sufficiency of allegations supporting these markets below.
1.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead an EV submarket.
A market is defined as “the area of effective competition – i.e., the arena within which
11
significant substitution in consumption or production occurs.” Epic Games, Inc v. Apple, 67 F.4th
12
946, 975 (9th Cir. 2023) (citing Ohio v. Am. Express Co., 585 U.S. 529, 543 (2018)). “A market
13
comprises ‘any grouping of sales whose sellers, if unified by a monopolist or a hypothetical cartel’
14
could profitably raise prices above a competitive level.” Id. (citing Rebel Oil Co., Inc. v. Atl.
15
16
Richfield Co., 51 F.3d 1421, 1434 (9th Cir. 1995)). Courts determine which products are included
17
in a certain market by evaluating what products have a “reasonable interchangeability of use or
18
sufficient cross-elasticity of demand with each other.” Id. (citing Hicks v. PGA Tour, Inc. 897 F.3d
19
1109, 1120 (9th Cir. 2018)). In making this determination, Courts evaluate empirical evidence,
20
such as a Small, Significant, Non-transitory Increase in Price (“SSNIP”) analysis, which uses
21
22
consumer data to establish whether a “hypothetical monopolist could profitably impose a Small,
Significant, Non-transitory Increase in Price above a competitive level.” Id.
23
24
Courts also consider whether a proposed market has the “practical indicia” of an
25
economically distinct market, including “[1] industry or public recognition of the [market] as a
26
separate economic entity, [2] the product’s peculiar characteristics and uses, [3] unique production
27
facilities, [4] distinct customers, [5] distinct prices, [6] sensitivity to price changes, and [7]
28
specialized vendors.” Id. (citing Brown Shoe v. U.S., 370 U.S. 294, 325 (1962)). A submarket
8
PDF Page 10
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 9 of 30
1
within a general product market can constitute a distinct market for purposes of an anti-trust claim.
2
Hicks, 897 F.3d at 1120; see Lucas Automotive Engineering, Inc. v. Bridgestone/Firestone, Inc.,
3
275 F.3d 762 (9th Cir. 2001) (“Lucas Auto.”) (holding that tires originally sold with vintage
4
automobiles could plausibly be a distinct submarket within the general market of all other tires
5
which could be used for vintage automobiles).
6
Plaintiffs define the EV market as “battery-electric motor vehicles designed and sold to be
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
operated on public streets.” SCAC ¶ 39. The Court reiterates its holding that Plaintiffs have
plausibly alleged the existence of an EV market distinct from vehicles that use internal-
10
combustion engines (“ICE vehicles”). FCAC Order, at 9. As previously stated, EVs have peculiar
11
characteristics and uses, traveling shorter distances and requiring frequent charging. SCAC ¶ 44.
12
EVs and ICE vehicles require separate manufacturing processes and production facilities. See id.
13
¶ 52. For example, ICE vehicle plants are not accustomed to sourcing, producing, and
14
manufacturing battery packs for EVs. See id. Additionally, EVs are constructed with a different
15
16
17
kind of chassis, or frame, than ICE vehicles, and as a result, ICE production facilities cannot easily
be converted in EV production facilities. Id.
Plaintiffs further allege that EVs cost more than similarly equipped ICE vehicles. See id. ¶
18
19
40. For example, in April 2022, the average price of EVs was above $65,000, while all other
20
motor vehicles cost an average of $20,000 less. See id. Plaintiffs claim that “consumers do not
21
22
view EVs and ICE vehicles as interchangeable products”—indeed, a recent study reports that
“96% of EV owners will only buy another EV for their next vehicle.” Id. ¶ 45. For example,
23
24
Ford—a U.S. automaker—publicized its decision to reorganize its company and separate EVs and
25
ICE vehicles into separate businesses. See id. ¶ 51. As such, Plaintiffs plausibly alleged that the
26
public and industry analysts recognize EVs as a separate product market or submarket. See id. ¶
27
39.
28
9
PDF Page 11
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 10 of 30
Defendant argues that In re German Automotive Manufacturers Antitrust Litigation
1
2
(“German Auto.) weighs against finding the existence of an EV market. The Court disagrees, as
3
German Auto. presented distinct factual circumstances. In German Auto., the plaintiffs proposed a
4
market consisting entirely of diesel engine cars. Although the complaint implicitly acknowledged
5
6
that diesel engine cars competed with other cars that offered equivalent environmental and fuelefficiency benefits, the plaintiffs’ market definition excluded all such cars. Here, Plaintiffs
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
proposed market consists of zero-emission battery-electric cars. Unlike in German Auto., there are
no options that offer similar or equivalent zero-emission vehicles.
10
Lucas Auto., however, is an insightful analog. There, the Ninth Circuit held that tire brands
11
that were used when a vintage car was first introduced could plausibly constitute a distinct market
12
from tire brands offered well-after the car was introduced, even though both brands could be used
13
on the vintage car today. 275 F.3d at 768. This holding was based, in part, on evidence suggesting
14
that vintage car consumers “absolutely insist[ed]” upon the original brand tires. Id. The Ninth
15
16
Circuit stated that “a legitimate inference can be drawn between the categorical insistence of
17
customers on, and to some degree their very strong preference for, [a product] and the expectation
18
that should the price of such [product] be increased, these customers would nonetheless purchase
19
the now-costlier version rather than substitute a less expensive, less authentic model.” Id.
20
Familiarly, here, Plaintiffs allege that 96% of EV owners would get an EV as their next car, which
21
creates a “legitimate inference” that these owners would purchase a costlier version. SCAC ¶ 51.2
22
Thus, Plaintiffs sufficiently plead the existence of an EV market.
23
24
25
26
27
28
2
The fact that the Lucas Auto. Court had some evidence specific to price-inelasticity does not
diminish its relevance because: (1) that court was considering a motion for summary judgment
with a much higher standard, and (2) the evidence of price-inelasticity was relatively
underwhelming (e.g., a declarant “estimate[d]” that one-third of members of a vintage car club
would be willing to pay more for original tires.) 275 F.3d at 767–68.
10
PDF Page 12
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 11 of 30
1
2
3
2.
Plaintiffs sufficiently allege Tesla Repair Services, and the TeslaCompatible Parts, are cognizable, single-brand aftermarkets.
The relevant market can be a “single-brand aftermarket” where “demand for a good is
entirely dependent on the prior purchase of a durable good in a foremarket.” Epic Games, 67 F.4th
4
5
6
7
a single brand-aftermarket. An evaluation of the relevant law is below.
In Eastman Kodak Co v. Image Tech. Servs., Inc., 504 U.S. 451, the plaintiffs alleged that
8
Kodak, which manufactured and sold photocopiers, engaged in anticompetitive conduct that
9
harmed the aftermarket for replacement parts and servicing of Kodak photocopiers. Kodak
10
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
at 976 (emphasis omitted). The parties disagree on the proper test for determining the existence of
claimed that, because it did not have market power in the photocopier market, it could not
plausibly have market power in a single-brand aftermarket. Id. at 466. Kodak’s reasoning went as
12
13
follows: because the photocopier market was a competitive market in which it did not have market
14
power, consumers in that photocopier market would be able to identify Kodak’s attempts to charge
15
supracompetitive prices in the parts and services aftermarket and choose to buy a different
16
photocopier. Id. The existence of competition in the foremarket would discipline anti-competitive
17
18
conduct in the aftermarket, and it was thus irrational and implausible for Kodak to engage in anticompetitive conduct in an aftermarket when it did not have market power in the foremarket. Id.
19
20
21
The Supreme Court rejected this argument, finding that Kodak could engage in anti-competitive
conduct in single-brand aftermarkets without possessing market power in the foremarket. Even if
22
there was competition in the foremarket, the Court stated that consumers may not be aware of the
23
high prices in the aftermarket because of the difficulty most consumers would face in determining
24
maintenance prices for “complex, durable equipment.” Id. at 473–75. The Court further held that
25
the high cost of switching photocopiers would prevent existing consumers who learned about the
26
supracompetitive prices of services and repairs from switching. Thus, these consumers would be
27
28
11
PDF Page 13
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 12 of 30
1
2
“locked in” and forced to “tolerate some level of service price increases before changing
equipment brands.” Id. at 476.
3
Subsequently, the Ninth Circuit elaborated on the Kodak holding when presented with
4
similar claims where a defendant allegedly harmed a single-brand aftermarket without market
5
6
power in the foremarket. The Ninth Circuit found that contractual obligations were not a
“cognizable source of market power.” Thus, circumstances in which a “consumer’s selection of a
7
8
9
10
particular brand in the competitive market [was] the functional equivalent of a contractual
commitment,” could not form the basis for antitrust claims. Newcal Indus., Inc. v. Ikon Office
Solution, 513 F.3d at 1047 (citing Forsyth v. Humana, 114 F.3d 1467, 1476 (9th Cir. 1997))
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
12
13
Recounting the history of Kodak and Newcal, the Ninth Circuit discussed the issues
presented by a lack of power in the foremarket in Epic Games¸ and aggregated the various
considerations, stating:
14
“to establish a single-brand aftermarket, a plaintiff must show: (1) the
challenged aftermarket restrictions are ‘not generally known’ when
consumers make their foremarket purchase; (2) ‘significant’
information costs prevent accurate life-cycle pricing; (3) ‘significant’
monetary or non-monetary switching costs exist; and (4) general
market-definition principles regarding cross-elasticity of demand do
not undermine the proposed single-brand market.”
15
16
17
18
67 F.4th at 977.
19
Here, Defendant alleges that Plaintiffs must meet all four Epic Games factors to establish
20
21
its single-brand aftermarket. Plaintiffs, however, argue that these factors only apply to cases in
22
which defendants do not have market power in the foremarket. Plaintiffs claim that, because they
23
allege that Defendant has market power in the EV market, and the Epic Games factors derive from
24
concerns about a lack of market power in the foremarket, these factors do not apply. This Court
25
agrees.
26
The Kodak Court established the information and switching costs factors to address
27
28
Kodak’s argument that it was impossible for a defendant to have market power in an aftermarket
12
PDF Page 14
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 13 of 30
1
without having market power in the foremarket. Eastman Kodak, at 504 U.S. at 467. In fact, the
2
Kodak Court explicitly declined to extend its analysis to a situation in which a defendant has a
3
market power in the foremarket. Id. at 465 n.10 (declining to address respondents’ argument that
4
Kodak had market power in the foremarket because it was not raised in their opposition to the
5
petition for certiorari, and stating that it would decide the case on the “premise . . . that
6
competition exists in the equipment market.”). The Ninth Circuit, in Newcal and Epic Games,
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
acknowledged that these factors were established to determine whether competition in the
foremarket would be able to “discipline” a defendant’s conduct in the aftermarket. See Newcal,
10
513 F.3d at 1050; Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 946. In both cases, the Ninth Circuit recognized that
11
these inquiries were intended to evaluate whether consumers “ma[d]e a knowing choice to restrict
12
their aftermarket options when they decide in the initial (competitive) market to enter a [] . . .
13
contract.” Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 980–81 (emphasis added) (citing Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1050).3
14
From a practical perspective, the relevance of information costs, switching costs, and
15
16
general knowledge of restrictions is reduced where a defendant has market power in the
17
foremarket. Market power is defined as the power to “force a purchaser to do something he would
18
not do in a competitive market.” Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 2080. Consumers in a foremarket
19
within which a company has market power have minimal ability to discipline the company’s
20
conduct in aftermarkets, regardless of information costs, switching costs, and general awareness of
21
restrictions.
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
3
For example, in Forsyth v. Humana, Inc., plaintiffs proposed a submarket that consisted of acute
care hospitals used by consumers insured by Humana, as supported by the fact that the vast
majority of Humana insureds used one acute care hospital as a result of Humana’s contractual
disincentives. 114 F.3d at 1476. The Ninth Circuit rejected this argument because the boundaries
of the market were defined by the consumers’ contractual obligations to Humana, which was an
improper basis to establish a market. Id. The Court held, however, that “to succeed in the face of
the contractual tie-in created by the insurance policies, the plaintiffs would have to make a
showing of monopoly power in the health insurance market, and there is no evidence of this.” Id.
13
PDF Page 15
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 14 of 30
1
The Court finds that Plaintiffs have (1) sufficiently alleged that Defendant has market
2
power in the EV foremarket, and (2) sufficiently alleged the existence of single-brand aftermarkets
3
for Tesla Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts. Arguendo, even if Plaintiffs have not
4
properly alleged market power in the EV market, Plaintiffs properly alleged the existence of these
5
6
aftermarkets under the Epic Games factors.
a.
7
8
9
10
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead that Tesla possesses market power in
the EV Market.
Market power is defined as the power to “force a purchaser to do something he would not
do in a competitive market.” Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 2080. “The existence of such power
ordinarily is inferred from the seller’s possession of a predominant share of the market.” “Courts
generally require a 65% market share to establish a prima facie case of market power.” Image
12
13
Tech. Servs., Inc. v. Eastman Kodak Co., 125 F.3d 1195, 1206 (9th Cir. 1997) (citing American
14
Tobacco Co. v. United States, 328 U.S. 781, 797 (1946)); see Dreamstime.com, LLC v. Google
15
LLC, 54 F. 4th 1130, 1137 n.5 (9th Cir. 2022).
16
17
18
Here, Plaintiffs allege that Defendant had 65% to 80% market share in the EV foremarket
during the class period. SCAC ¶ 53. This factor is uncontested by Defendant. Consequently, the
Court finds that Defendant properly alleged market power in the EV foremarket.
19
20
21
22
b.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead the existence of aftermarkets for
Tesla Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts under
general market definition principles.
Plaintiffs must demonstrate that their proposed aftermarkets show the absence of
23
interchangeability and cross-elasticity of demand. In Eastman Kodak, the Supreme Court held that
24
the respondents’ services and parts aftermarkets met this criterion “[b]ecause service and parts for
25
Kodak equipment [were] not interchangeable with other manufacturers’ service and parts, the
26
27
relevant market from the Kodak equipment owner’s perspective [was] composed of only those
companies that service Kodak machines.” 504 U.S. at 482.
28
14
PDF Page 16
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 15 of 30
Here, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla’s electric vehicles “are designed differently and utilize
1
2
different parts that are not interchangeable with other EVs.” SCAC ¶ 58. A “Tesla EV owner must
3
bring his or her EV to a service provider who specializes in the maintenance and repair of Tesla
4
EVs.” Id. ¶ 59. Thus, service and parts for Teslas are not interchangeable with other EV
5
6
manufacturers. As a result, the aftermarkets are properly limited to Tesla-Compatible Parts and
Tesla Repair Services.
7
Defendant claims that Plaintiffs insufficiently plead that the proper geographic market for
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
these aftermarkets is the United States. According to Defendant, a geographic market should be
10
limited to the area “where buyers can turn for alternative sources of supply,” and Plaintiffs do not
11
explain how “repair services in New Jersey could plausibly be a substitute for repair services in
12
California for a Tesla owner.” Motion, at 19 (citing Reilly v. Apple, Inc., 578 F. Supp. 3d 1098, 1109
13
(N.D. Cal. 2022)). A market should “reflect commercial realities.” U.S. v. Grinnell Corp., 384
14
U.S. 563, 572 (1966). Even where a consumer may primarily receive services from a local
15
16
17
provider, a geographic market that covers that the entire United States is appropriate where “the
business of providing such a service is operated on a national level.” Id. at 572. For purposes of a
18
motion to dismiss, Plaintiffs have plausibly alleged that the Defendant implemented its policies on
19
a nationwide level.4
20
c.
21
22
Even if Plaintiffs were required to satisfy the Epic Games
factors, Plaintiffs sufficiently plead the existence of
aftermarkets.
Regardless of the existence of market power in the foremarket, Plaintiffs’ allegations
23
satisfy the Epic Games factors for purposes of surviving a motion to dismiss.
24
25
26
27
28
4
Defendant incorrectly claims that this Court already found in its prior order that Plaintiffs failed
to allege price sensitivity. Motion, at 10. The language from the Court’s order that Defendant cites
to for this contention addresses Plaintiffs’ allegations regarding price insensitivity in the EV
market, not in the Tesla-Compatible Parts or Tesla Services Market. FCAC Order, at 9 (“Plaintiffs
do not allege that EVs are insensitive.”)
15
PDF Page 17
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 16 of 30
(i)
1
2
Plaintiffs sufficiently allege they were generally unaware.
The first requirement, that the restrictions in the aftermarket are not generally known, is a
3
“crucial” one. Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 977 (quoting Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 477). This
4
unawareness requirement places “the burden on a plaintiff to ‘rebut the economic presumption
5
that . . . consumers make a knowing choice to restrict their aftermarket options’ when they make a
6
foremarket purchase.” Id. (quoting Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1050). “Kodak does not impose a
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
requirement that a plaintiff show ‘complete ignorance’ of a defendant’s aftermarket restrictions; it
need only show that the restrictions are not ‘generally known.’” Id. at 979 n.10. While the Ninth
10
Circuit has not defined what, exactly, “amounts to general unawareness,” a plaintiff must present
11
at least some evidence to fulfill this prong. Id. at 979 n.10.
12
13
14
Plaintiffs provide an assortment of evidence that makes a plausible showing that
consumers were generally unaware of the aftermarket restrictions. In the SCAC, Plaintiffs cite an
article depicting Tesla owners that have experienced “unexpected headaches” with their cars,
15
16
which speaks to a general lack of consumer awareness of the alleged issues with Tesla EVs prior
17
to purchase. SCAC ¶ 87. Further, the SCAC indicates that Plaintiffs and consumers, generally,
18
were not aware of the repair restrictions and service center limitations described in the complaint.
19
See id. ¶¶ 10–28, 84–87.
20
21
Notably, Plaintiffs go further. They reason that consumers were unaware of the repair
restrictions in their warranties because Tesla misleads consumers into believing their EVs require
22
little to no maintenance, have fewer moving parts, and receive over-the-air software updates. See
23
24
id. ¶¶ 61, 94–95. See id. Despite Tesla publicizing freely available manuals, its electronic parts
25
catalog, and Toolbox diagnostic software, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla restricts individual shops and
26
car owners from conducting everything but the most minimal repair. See id. ¶ 88.
27
28
To this point, Defendant argues that Plaintiffs concede that consumers are knowledgeable
of Tesla’s restrictions as they are “now widely documented.” Motion, at 7 (emphasis added). The
16
PDF Page 18
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 17 of 30
1
critical and relevant inquiry is whether Tesla purchasers were generally unaware of aftermarket
2
restrictions at the time of foremarket purchase. If the Court were to follow Defendant’s logic, the
3
filing of this litigation could have made Tesla’s shortcomings and restrictions widely known,
4
thereby precluding Plaintiffs from pleading their case.
5
6
Several of the Plaintiffs purchased their Tesla EVs prior to the articles, tweets, and online
forums presented in the Second Consolidated Amended Complaint. Based on evidence cited by
7
8
9
United States District Court
Northern District of California
10
Plaintiffs, it is plausible that a significant portion of Tesla purchasers were unaware of their
vehicles’ forthcoming service and repair issues at the time of purchase. See, e.g., SCAC ¶ 87.
Plaintiffs must also sufficiently plead that they “did not knowingly enter a contract” that
11
would lock them into the aftermarkets associated with their foremarket Tesla EV. Epic Games, 67
12
F.4th at 977. Plaintiffs’ unawareness hinges on whether Plaintiffs were aware of the aftermarket
13
restrictions contained in their EV warranty. Tesla’s Parts, Body, & Paint Repair Limited Warranty
14
states that the warranty “may be voided, or coverage may be excluded, due to lack of or improper
15
16
maintenance, installation, service or repairs.” SCAC ¶¶ 182–86. Though Plaintiffs cite, and
17
Defendant highlights, an article describing consumers choosing “not to use independent repair
18
shops or aftermarket parts . . . for fear of losing warranty coverage,” it is plausible that consumers,
19
generally, were and remain unaware of these repair restrictions. SCAC ¶ 189. It is also plausible
20
that consumers learned of these issues after their Tesla EV purchase, either after coming across
21
such an article, or running into their own maintenance issue. In either case, consumer awareness,
22
conceivably, arose after purchase.
23
24
25
(ii)
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead significant information costs.
The second requirement is that “‘significant’ information costs prevent accurate life-cycle
26
pricing.” Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 977; see also Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 473–74. For
27
example, in Eastman Kodak, the Supreme Court held that photocopiers were “complex, durable
28
equipment” that presented significant information costs because they required a “sophisticated
17
PDF Page 19
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 18 of 30
1
analysis,” including “availability of products needed to operate, upgrade, or enhance the initial
2
equipment, as well as service and repair costs, including estimates of breakdown frequency, nature
3
of repairs, price of service and parts, length of ‘downtime,’ and losses incurred from downtime.”
4
Id. at 473–74.
5
6
Electric vehicles are as complex, if not more so, than the photocopiers addressed in
Eastman Kodak. Plaintiffs plausibly allege that “[i]t is difficult, if not impossible, for a consumer
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
to accurately forecast how much repair and maintenance [] will be required” for their EVs. SCAC
¶ 103. Further, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla’s public misstatements distort the lifecycle costs for
10
Tesla. These alleged misrepresentations could plausibly hinder consumer ability to accurately
11
price the life of their vehicle at the time of purchase and make knowledgeable purchasing
12
decisions. See Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 473 (“For the service-market price to affect equipment
13
demand, consumers must inform themselves of the total cost of the “package”—equipment,
14
service, and parts—at the time of purchase; that is, consumers must engage in accurate lifecycle
15
16
17
pricing.”).
Plaintiffs also claim that lifecycle pricing is impossible because EVs are “a relatively new
18
product and Tesla is a relatively new producer.” SCAC ¶ 105. Because of the recency of this
19
industry, common variables of EV ownership may be extremely difficult to determine at the time
20
of purchase, “including the number of accidents one may have, how many miles the car will drive,
21
and how long the buyer will own the car,” making lifecycle pricing difficult. Id. at ¶ 104.
22
Plaintiffs further allege that three of the largest data providers used by automotive industry
23
24
professionals to estimate repair costs have no data on Tesla EVs. See SCAC ¶ 106. Thus, even if
25
a consumer wanted to and could synthesize the data presented to them to accurately price a Tesla,
26
they may not have the critical means to do so. Although the SCAC does provide an alternative
27
source for maintenance costs, see SCAC ¶¶ 204, 122, this does not defeat their argument. While
28
average yearly maintenance cost is one of the significant components to accurate lifecycle pricing
18
PDF Page 20
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 19 of 30
1
of a vehicle, it does not include the cost of collisions which can be significant. Further, it is not
2
clear when this information was posted online, and whether consumers would have had access as
3
early as 2019.
4
5
6
Regardless, Plaintiffs identify inconsistencies in Tesla’s sales and services that add
additional barriers to lifecycle pricing. Plaintiffs allege that Tesla sells its parts inconsistently both
to its own service centers and TACCs, which can frustrate a consumer’s vehicle price knowledge
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
while keeping that consumer in the dark about how much the EV will cost long-term. See SCAC ¶
163. Plaintiffs further document a recurring practice by Tesla of refusing maintenance following
10
routine trivial fixes by third-party repair shops, or charging the full price to replace an out-of-
11
warranty part with minimal damage. Id. ¶¶ 188, 206–08. Plaintiffs have met their pleading burden
12
under this prong. It is beyond the scope of these proceedings to delve further into the distinctions
13
between the appropriate lifecycle pricing mechanisms and the mechanisms Plaintiffs use to
14
demonstrate market power, and ultimately becomes a question for the fact finders.
15
16
17
(iii)
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead high switching costs.
Third, a plaintiff must show that costs prohibit consumers from switching between market
18
goods such that a locked-in effect in the relevant market occurs. See Epic Games, 67 F.4th at
19
979–80; Eastman Kodak Co., 504 U.S. at 476–77 (“If the cost of switching is high, consumers
20
who already have purchased the equipment . . . will tolerate some level of service-price increases
21
before changing equipment brands.”). Switching costs must be “significant” to define a market.
22
Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S at 473; See Klein v. Facebook, Inc., 580 F. Supp. 3d 743, 781 (C.D. Cal.
23
24
2022) (holding that social media services have a high switching cost because users will be
25
reluctant to switch to a new platform “unless many other users make the switch simultaneously”).
26
A plaintiff need not make an extensive showing of switching costs; among other things, a plaintiff
27
can point to the “heavy initial outlay” of the foremarket good and brand-specific purchases.
28
Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S at 477.
19
PDF Page 21
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 20 of 30
1
In Eastman Kodak, the Court stated that evidence showing “the heavy initial outlay for
2
Kodak equipment, combined with the required support material that works only with Kodak
3
equipment, ma[de] switching costs very high for existing Kodak customers.” 504 U.S. at 477. In
4
other words, the high cost of Kodak’s complex foremarket equipment relative to and combined
5
6
with the restricted, necessary services and parts in the aftermarket made for high switching costs.
Plaintiffs tell a similar story here. Tesla EVs range from $40,000 to $110,000, and a
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
purchase can be “one of the biggest purchases” in a consumer’s life. SCAC ¶ 99. Plaintiffs also
allege these purchases are often financed through loan or lease with specified contract terms that
10
exacerbate the total cost. See id. Plaintiffs further allege that Tesla EVs have some of the lowest
11
resale values in the EV market, making Tesla owners suffer a substantial loss if they were to make
12
a brand switch. See SCAC ¶ 100. This is in addition to the EV owners’ purchase of peripheral
13
14
products that only work with Tesla EVs, like home chargers that cost around $400. SCAC ¶ 101.
And even if they did make the switch to another EV brand, consumers could not escape Tesla’s
15
16
approach to alleged repair restrictions as other EV brands “not only have limited sales volume, but
17
. . . have also adopted similar policies, practices, and restrictions as . . . Tesla.” SCAC ¶ 82. The
18
high initial cost, investment required for peripheral products, and limited exit options sufficiently
19
support the existence of switching costs.
20
21
C.
Monopolization and Attempted Monopolization under Section 2 of the
Sherman Act
22
The Second Consolidated Amended Complaint alleges that Defendant monopolized, or
23
attempted to monopolize, the markets for Tesla Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts, in
24
violation of Section 2 of the Sherman Act. SCAC ¶¶ 242–263; 15 U.S.C. § 2. The Court
25
addresses each of these allegations in turn. A Section 2 monopolization claim “has two elements:
26
(1) the possession of monopoly power in the relevant market and (2) the willful acquisition or
27
28
20
PDF Page 22
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 21 of 30
1
2
3
maintenance of that power as distinguished from growth or development as a consequence of a
superior product, business acumen, or historic accident.” Grinnell, 384 U.S. at 570–71.
a.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead that Tesla possesses monopoly power
in the relevant markets.
4
5
A plaintiff must establish that a defendant possesses monopoly power, which is the ability
6
“to control prices or exclude competition.” Grinnell, 384 U.S. at 571. Antitrust plaintiffs can
7
establish that a defendant possesses monopoly power via direct or indirect evidence. To establish
8
monopoly power via direct evidence, a plaintiff must provide “direct proof of injury to
9
competition,” including “evidence of restricted output and supracompetitive prices.” Forsyth, 114
10
F.3d at 1476. To prove monopoly power via “indirect evidence,” the plaintiff must “(1) define the
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
relevant market, (2) show that the defendant owns a dominant share of that market, and (3) show
12
13
14
15
16
17
18
19
20
21
22
that there are significant barriers to entry and show that existing competitors lack the capacity to
increase their output.” Id.
Here, Plaintiffs provided direct and indirect evidence of monopoly power in the Telsa
Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts markets.
i.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead monopoly power in the Tesla
Repair Services market.
Plaintiffs provided sufficient direct and indirect evidence of monopoly power in the Tesla
Repair Services market to survive a motion to dismiss.
For direct evidence, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla has restricted output by reducing supply of
service-providers. Tesla has accomplished this, in part, by refusing to invest in its own service
23
center infrastructure, and limiting the growth of TACCs. Id. ¶ 151. Though Tesla EV sales have
24
25
26
27
28
increased substantially, service offerings have not. Id. ¶ 85. This has created delay and allowed
Tesla to charge supracompetitive prices.
Plaintiffs also provided sufficient indirect evidence of monopoly power. As discussed
above, Plaintiffs sufficiently defined the Tesla Repair Services market. Further, Plaintiffs plead
21
PDF Page 23
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 22 of 30
1
that Tesla has a dominant share of this market because virtually all Tesla services are performed
2
by Tesla or its “limited network of Tesla-Approved Collision Centers,” of which Tesla maintains
3
such tight control over that they are not competitors. Id. ¶ 67. This is because they must rely on
4
Tesla to source Tesla-Compatible Parts and to set pricing. See id. ¶ 66. To become a TACC, body
5
6
shops must purchase expensive equipment and undergo extensive training. Id. ¶¶ 170–72.
Plaintiffs also sufficiently allege the existence of barriers to entry into the Tesla Repair
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
Services aftermarket. Tesla maintains its power over service due to the unique, computer-like
nature of its EV. Only Tesla can provide the full range of EV repairs and maintenance. SCAC ¶
10
90. It does this, Plaintiffs claim, by designing Tesla EVs to require remote diagnostic and
11
software updates that only it can provide. Id. Even if independent service providers have access
12
to the Toolbox software which offers some repair services, it is limited, expensive, and inadequate
13
to the point that consumers must still report to Tesla for such repairs. Id. ¶¶ 90, 144, 165. Indeed,
14
many of the parts used for maintenance and repairs will not function until they are coded by Tesla,
15
16
17
18
and no other provider can code these parts. Id. ¶¶ 92, 138-43, 147–50. Thus, Plaintiffs sufficiently
plead monopoly power in the Tesla Repair Services market.
ii.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead monopoly power in the TeslaCompatible Parts market.
19
20
21
Plaintiffs also provided direct and indirect evidence of monopoly power in the TeslaCompatible Parts markets to survive a motion to dismiss. For direct evidence, Plaintiffs allege that
22
Tesla has excluded manufacturer competitors and restricted output preventing Original Equipment
23
Manufacturers (“OEMs”) from selling “to anyone other than Tesla.” Id. ¶ 77. Plaintiffs also allege
24
that though Tesla may sell parts directly to consumers, it only does so on a limited basis. Id.
25
26
Plaintiffs also provide indirect evidence of monopoly power. Plaintiffs make the same
indirect argument as to Defendant’s near total control over the repair services market. Plaintiffs
27
28
further plausibly allege the significant barriers to entry and increased output for potential
22
PDF Page 24
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 23 of 30
1
competitors. For example, once consumers purchase a Tesla, similar to services, they are locked
2
into the Tesla-Compatible Parts aftermarket. Like Kodak, Plaintiffs allege there is no viable
3
substitute for Tesla parts and that most Tesla-Compatible parts are not interchangeable with other
4
EV parts. SCAC ¶ 72. Tesla’s batteries, for instance, cannot be serviced or replaced by anyone
5
6
but Tesla. Id. ¶ 179. Indeed, many of the parts used for maintenance and repairs will not function
until they are coded by Tesla, and no other provider can code these parts. SCAC ¶¶ 92–93.
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
Plaintiffs further allege Tesla also prevents OEMs from manufacturing and selling TeslaCompatible Parts to anyone other than Tesla. SCAC ¶ 144. Thus, potential parts competitors face
10
numerous barriers to entry into the market, and Plaintiffs sufficiently plead monopoly power in the
11
Tesla-Compatible Parts market.
12
13
14
b.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead willful acquisition of power and
anticompetitive conduct.
Defendant recognizes, and Plaintiffs concede, that monopoly power on its own is not a
15
violation of the Sherman Act. “Mere possession of monopoly power, and the concomitant
16
charging of monopoly prices, is . . . an important element of the free market system.”
17
Dreamstime.com, LLC, 54 F.4th at 1137. The possession of monopoly power “will not be found
18
unlawful unless it is accompanied by an element of anticompetitive conduct.” Verizon Commc’ns
19
20
21
Inc. v. Law Offs. of Curtis V. Trinko, 540 U.S. 398, 407 (2004). To this end Plaintiffs plead that
Tesla’s conduct is anticompetitive. Plaintiffs plead that a series of Tesla decisions led to
22
insufficient availability of replacement parts and repair services to increase Tesla’s profits.
23
Plaintiffs claim Tesla was incentivized to keep as much market share of the aftermarkets as it
24
could with the expectation that these markets would become profitable in the long term. See
25
SCAC ¶ 151. This promise of profits explains, Plaintiffs allege, Tesla’s anticompetitive conduct
26
and why it has not invested further into the service and parts aftermarkets. See id. ¶ 150. Beyond
27
28
Tesla’s barriers to entry, limited diagnostic tools, misrepresentations, and warranty woes,
23
PDF Page 25
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 24 of 30
1
Plaintiffs allege Tesla has de facto exclusivity agreements preventing OEM and suppliers from
2
manufacturing Tesla-Compatible Parts for anyone other than Tesla. See id. ¶¶ 157–58. Tesla has
3
also authored cease and desist letters preventing independent repair shops from offering Tesla
4
repair services. See id. ¶ 162.
5
6
It is important not to confuse allegations of anticompetitive conduct with stifling the
innovation of a unique and cutting-edge consumer good. Anticompetitive conduct does not
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
include “product improvement” nor innovations that attract consumers to a particular product due
to price, service, or terms advantages. Allied Orthopedic Appliances Inc. v. Tyco Health Care
10
Grp. LP, 592 F.3d 991, 999 (9th Cir. 2010). The existence of the alleged markets, market power,
11
and anticompetitive conduct are “factual question[s]” that “remain open for resolution” either for
12
or against Plaintiffs. Newcal, 513 F.3d at 1051. At this stage of the proceedings, Plaintiffs have
13
sufficiently alleged monopolization, or alternatively, attempted monopolization, in the Tesla
14
Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts markets in violation Section 2 of the Sherman Act.
15
16
D.
Tying Claims under Section 1 of the Sherman Act
17
Plaintiffs further allege that Defendant’s unlawful tying arrangement violates Section 1 of
18
the Sherman Act. SCAC ¶¶ 264–75. A tying arrangement is “an agreement by a party to sell one
19
product but only on the condition that the buyer also purchases a different (or tied) product, or at
20
least agrees that he will not purchase that product from any other supplier.” Kodak, 504 U.S. at
21
22
461. To establish the existence of a tie, a plaintiff must demonstrate that the arrangement includes
two or more distinct products, that the tie is “forc[ing] the buyer into a purchase of a tied product,”
23
24
and that the tie is unlawful. Id.
25
Here, Plaintiffs allege three separate tying arrangements: (1) the Tesla EV Market
26
foremarket is tied to both the Tesla-Repair Services and Tesla-Compatible Parts aftermarkets (2)
27
the Tesla-Compatible Parts aftermarket is tied to the Tesla Repair Services aftermarket, and (3) the
28
24
PDF Page 26
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 25 of 30
1
2
3
4
5
6
Tesla Repair Services aftermarket is tied to the Tesla-Compatible Parts aftermarket. See SCAC ¶¶
269–71. As discussed below, Plaintiffs have sufficiently plead both prongs.
1.
Plaintiffs sufficiently allege the existence of distinct products.
To constitute two separate products, “[t]here must be sufficient consumer demand so that
it is efficient for a firm to provide” the products separately. See Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 462
(citing Jefferson Parish Hospital Dist. No. 2 v. Hyde, 466 U.S. 2 (1984)). “The efficiency showing
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
may be inferred from ‘more readily observed facts.’ These include consumer requests to offer the
products separately, disentangling of the products by competitors, analogous practices in related
10
markets, and the defendant’s historical practice.” Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 995; see Eastman
11
Kodak, 504 U.S. at 463 (finding sufficient at the 12(b)(6) stage allegations that “consumers would
12
purchase service without parts” and that the defendant had sold them “separately in the past.”)
13
14
In Epic Games, the Ninth Circuit Court of Appeals found the district court “clearly erred”
by not focusing on two products’ sufficient consumer demand when the district court found no tie.
15
16
67 F.4th at 996. Contrary to Apple’s assertion, Apple’s app distribution software and in-app
17
purchasing (IAP) platform could be separate markets because Apple separated them in other
18
contexts. Id. The court further found that because other companies sought to develop their own
19
IAPs, there was evidence of efficiency in and a separate market for the tied product. Id.
20
21
22
The Supreme Court in Eastman Kodak held that a tying arrangement existed between two
aftermarket products: Kodak parts and Kodak service. 504 U.S. at 463. The Court held that
petitioner provided sufficient evidence that “[a]t least some consumers would purchase service
23
24
without parts, because some service does not require parts, and some consumers, those who self-
25
service for example, would purchase parts without service.” Id. Kodak argued that there could
26
never be separate markets service for service and parts because there is no demand for parts
27
separate from service. Id. The Court, however, rejected this line of thinking because it would lead
28
to the illogical result that there could not separate markets for “cameras and film, computers and
25
PDF Page 27
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 26 of 30
1
software, or automobiles and tires.” Id. The Court also concluded that Kodak’s attempts to
2
bifurcate customers with different pay-rates—depending on whether they “serviced their own
3
machines or received third-party maintenance”—suggested product separation. Id. at 462.
4
5
6
Here, focusing on the first alleged tie, Tesla EVs in the foremarket can be separated from
the parts and services aftermarkets. Plaintiffs bring their claims because of Tesla’s chosen
practice to limit access to its service and parts to only Tesla and its approved providers, eroding
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
Tesla’s service quality and secondary market value. See SCAC ¶¶ 3, 7. Plaintiffs also make the
contrast between automobile providers like Ford and their relatively abundant service and parts
10
provisions and that of Tesla’s. See id. ¶ 85. That collision centers and body shops outside of
11
Tesla are seeking to receive training, equipment, and parts suggests that, like the in-app
12
purchasing platform in Epic Games, there is efficiency and separation between Tesla EVs and its
13
aftermarkets.
14
Between services and parts, Plaintiffs sufficiently allege there is sufficient demand and
15
16
efficiency because service and parts have been sold separately in the past and are still sold
17
separately. In Eastman Kodak, the Court found that Kodak’s “policy of allowing customers to
18
purchase parts on condition that they agree to service their own machines suggests that the
19
demand for parts can be separated from the demand for service.” 504 U.S. at 462 n.5. Similarly,
20
Tesla’s warranty discourages Tesla EV owners from receiving service outside of Tesla by
21
22
suggesting that the warranty “may be voided or coverage may be excluded due to improper
maintenance, service or repairs.” SCAC ¶¶ 182–83. Further, Tesla’s over-the-air software updates
23
24
and diagnostic reports do not require any parts. See SCAC ¶¶ 94–95. This separation of
25
consumers who received Tesla service and those who went outside of Tesla to receive service
26
suggests the existence of a separate market for its parts and a separate market for service and
27
repair.
28
26
PDF Page 28
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 27 of 30
2.
1
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead that the tying scheme coerced consumers.
2
“Even where a transaction involves separate products, it is not necessarily a tie; the seller
3
must also ‘force the buyer into the purchase of a tied product that the buyer either did not want at
4
all, or might have preferred to purchase elsewhere on different terms.’” Epic Games, 67 F.4th at
5
6
996 (citing Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 12).
Plaintiffs allege that consumers attempt to receive both services and parts outside of Tesla,
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
but are coerced into forgoing those options to stay within warranty. See SCAC ¶ 189.
Specifically, Tesla forces consumers to purchase the tied product by threatening to void warranties
10
if consumers use non-Tesla certified service providers or if they use non-OEM parts. See id.; See
11
Jefferson Parish, 466 U.S. at 12 (The seller must also “force the buyer into the purchase of a tied
12
product that the buyer either did not want at all or might have preferred to purchase elsewhere on
13
different terms.”). In Eastman Kodak, the plaintiffs were forced to receive services from only
14
Kodak due to unique machine parts, similarly, Tesla EV owners are limited in their options to
15
16
receive service and parts due to Tesla’s market power in the EV submarket and Tesla’s own
17
conduct. See Eastman Kodak, 504 U.S. at 482. The EV parts and repair aftermarkets for Tesla
18
EVs and other EVs/ICE vehicles are not substitutes for each other, meaning there is no cross
19
elasticity of demand; this further aides Plaintiffs in their argument. See SCAC ¶¶ 57-59.
20
21
Finally, Plaintiffs allege that Tesla excludes competition in the repairs and parts market by
limiting diagnostic tools and manuals (Id. ¶¶ 226(f), 246(c)) and misleading consumers (Id. ¶¶ 61,
22
94-95). Plaintiffs claim that there is an insignificant number of independent service providers
23
24
because of Tesla’s Repair Restrictions. Even the TACCs which are “independent”, are not really
25
because they must rely on Tesla to source Tesla-Compatible Parts and pricing. Id. ¶ 66. Thus,
26
Plaintiffs have sufficiently plead that Tesla’s tying scheme coerces customers into undesired
27
purchases.
28
27
PDF Page 29
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 28 of 30
3.
1
2
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead that the ties are unlawful.
“A tie can be unlawful pursuant to either a modified per se rule or the Rule of Reason. A
3
tie is per se unlawful if (1) the defendant has market power in the tying product market, and (2) the
4
“tying arrangement affects a ‘not insubstantial volume of commerce’ in the tied product market.”
5
6
Epic Games, 67 F.4th at 996–97 (quoting Blough v. Holland Realty, Inc., 574 F.3d 1084, 1089
(9th Cir. 2009)). As discussed above, Plaintiffs have sufficiently plead that Tesla possesses market
7
8
United States District Court
Northern District of California
9
power in all three markets. Further, given that Plaintiffs alleged that Tesla controls “virtually all”
of the commerce in the Tesla-Compatible Parts and Tesla Repair Services markets, it is plausible
10
to infer that these tying arrangements would affect a “not insubstantial volume of commerce” in
11
these markets. Thus, Plaintiffs have sufficiently plead tying claims.
12
E.
13
“The analysis under California's antitrust law mirrors the analysis under federal law
Plaintiffs sufficiently allege unlawful tying in violation of the Cartwright Act.
14
because the Cartwright Act, Cal. Bus. & Prof. Code § 16700 et seq., was modeled after the
15
16
Sherman Act.” County of Tuolumne v. Sonora Comm. Hosp., 236 F.3d 1148, 1160 (2001).
17
However, the Cartwright Act is distinct in that it does not apply claims in which “the tying item is
18
a service.” Morrison v. Viacom, Inc., 66 Cal. App. 4th 534, 546 (1998). In their opposition,
19
Plaintiffs appeared to concede that they were prohibited from asserting a tying claim under the
20
Cartwright Act based on Tesla Repair Services as the tying product. Oppo., at 21 fn.13 (“Tesla
21
22
asserts that Plaintiffs’ Cartwright Act claim alleging Tesla Repair Services as a tying product must
be dismissed. . . . Regarding that aspect and only that aspect of Plaintiffs’ claim, Tesla is correct.”)
23
24
As such, Plaintiffs’ Cartwright Act claim is dismissed to the extent it is based on a Tesla Repair
25
Services as the tying product. Plaintiffs’ Cartwright Act claims alleging that EVs and Tesla-
26
Compatible Parts as the tying products are maintained.
27
28
28
PDF Page 30
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 29 of 30
1
2
F.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead a combination in restraint of trade in violation of
the Cartwright Act.
Plaintiffs claim that Defendant’s de facto exclusivity agreements with the TACCs and
3
manufacturers constitute horizontal restraints that are per se violations of the Cartwright Act. The
4
5
Ninth Circuit has held that California courts would agree with its holding that hybrid agreements
6
are not per se violations. Dimidowich, 803 F.2d, at 1481–82. Thus, Plaintiffs’ claims are subject to
7
the Rule of Reason. Plaintiffs, again, argue that these restraints are per se violations of the law.
8
However, as stated above, plaintiff has not sufficiently plead that this hybrid conspiracy is a per se
9
violation. Thus, the Rule of Reason applies to these claims. The Rule of Reason applies
10
“essentially the same” regardless of “whether the alleged antitrust violation” is based on concerted
11
United States District Court
Northern District of California
or independent. As previously noted, Plaintiffs’ allegations regarding de facto exclusivity
12
13
14
15
agreements were sufficient to form the basis for independent unlawful restraints of trade. As such,
these allegations are sufficient to form the basis for concerted restraints on trade.
G.
Plaintiffs sufficiently plead a violation of the California Unfair Competition
Law (UCL).
16
17
Plaintiffs allege that defendant violated the UCL which prohibits any unlawful, unfair, or
18
fraudulent business practice. See id. ¶¶ 303, 310. The statute’s “purpose is to protect both
19
consumers and competitors by promoting fair competition in commercial markets for goods and
20
services.” Abbott Labs. v. Superior Court, 9 Cal. 5th 642, 651 (2020) (citing Kasky v. Nike,
21
Inc. 27 Cal.4th 939, 949 (2002)). “By proscribing any unlawful business practice, section 17200
22
23
borrows violations of other laws and treats them as unlawful practices that the unfair competition
law makes independently actionable.” Abbott Labs., 9 Cal. 5th at 651. (Internal citation omitted).
24
25
Here, Plaintiffs assert that Tesla engaged in both unlawful and unfair business practices. SCAC ¶¶
26
303, 310. Since Plaintiffs have sufficiently pled the elements for relief under the Sherman Act and
27
Cartwright Act, Plaintiffs sufficiently plead unlawful business practices in violation of the UCL.
28
29
PDF Page 31
Case 3:23-cv-01145-TLT Document 156 Filed 06/17/24 Page 30 of 30
1
2
3
4
5
6
V.
CONCLUSION
The Court finds that Plaintiffs have plausibly alleged a cause of action for monopolization
and unlawful tying under the Sherman act and causes of action under the Cartwright and
California UCL.
Accordingly, for the foregoing reasons the Court DENIES Defendant’s Motion as to
7
8
9
10
United States District Court
Northern District of California
11
claims 1 through 5 and 7. The Court further DENIES claim 6 to the extent it relies on EVs or
Tesla-Compatible Parts as a tying product. The Court GRANTS Defendant’s Motion, with
prejudice, as to claim 6 to the extent it relies on services as a tying product.
This resolves docket number 135.
12
IT IS SO ORDERED.
13
Dated: June 17, 2024
14
15
16
TRINA L. THOMPSON
United States District Judge
17
18
19
20
21
22
23
24
25
26
27
28
30